12127.pdf

Media

extracted text
1

Hunger, Under-nutrition and Food Security in India
NC Saxena
Contents
1

Executive summary

1.1
2

3

Policy recommendations
Understanding hunger

Dimensions of hunger
Self-reported hunger
3.1
Measuring hunger by calorie consumption

3.2
3.2.1

How many calories are needed for healthy living?

3.2.2

The official poverty line

3.3
3.4
3.5
3.6
3.7
4

IFPRTs composite index on hunger

BMI
Undernourished children
Women's malnutrition
Child mortality

Food security
Consumption and prices
4.1
Food
production, procurement and availability at the macro-level
4.2
Recent developments and imports
Global developments
4.3
Recent global financial crisis
4.3.1

4.2.1

Future scenario for India’s food production
4.4
Analysis of major programmes and policy options
5
Agricultural production
5.1
What needs to be done?
Agricultural labour and wage employment programmes
5.2
Public Distribution System (PDS)
5.3
Policy and procedural reforms
5.3.1
Fighting children’s malnutrition
5.4
5.1.1

2
3
5

8
8

10
13

15
16
17
20
24
26
27
27
29
32
33
33
34
36
37
39

41

43
46
47

5.5
Mid Day Meal Scheme (MDM)
Tribals and hunger
5.6
Supreme Court intervention
6
Improving accountability
7
Destitutes
7.1

51
53

Problems of delivery and implementation
7.2
8
Abbreviations
9
Bibliography

58

54
56
57

61
62

2

1

Executive summary

This paper examines the hunger and nutrition situation prevailing in India and
suggests policy measures for ensuring adequate food security at the household level,
particularly for marginalised groups, destitutes, women and children.

I

Despite rapid economic growth in the last two decades India is likely to slip behind
the first Millennium Development Goal (MDG) of cutting the proportion of hungry
people by half. Per capita availability as well as consumption of foodgrains in India
has declined since 1996; the percentage of underweight children has remained
stagnant between 1998 and 2006; and the calorie consumption of the bottom half of
the population has been consistently declining since 1987. In short, all indicators point
to the hard fact that endemic hunger continues to afflict a large proportion of Indian
population.
Hunger in simple terms is the desire to consume food. However due to an inadequate
diet over time the human body gets used to having less food than is necessary for
healthy development, and after a while the body does not even demand more food. In
such cases hunger is not expressed, though lower intake of essential calories, proteins,
fats, and micro-nutrients would result in under-development of the human mind and
body. Thus objective indicators such as calorie consumption, body mass index (BMI),
the proportion of malnourished children, and child mortality capture hunger more
scientifically than the subjective articulation by individuals.
Surveys on self-reported hunger depend on the responses of the head of the
household, often a man, who may not admit that he cannot provide even two square
meals to his dependents. Pride, self-image and dignity are issues here, which lead to a
deep sense of shame and reluctance on the part of the head of the households to
publicly admit their incapacity to provide for their families. This may result in under­
reporting on the number of meals family members are able to afford. Despite this
limitation, a recent UNDP survey (2008) of 16 districts in the seven poorest states of
India showed that for 7.5 per cent of respondents access to food is highly inadequate,
and for another 29 per cent of the households it is somewhat inadequate. A West
Bengal government survey too reported that 15 per cent families were facing
difficulties in arranging two square meals a day year round. These figures are
gloomier than the NSSO survey of the Ministry of Programme Implementation and
Statistics claiming a drastic decline in self-reported hunger in India from 16.1 to 1.9
percent in the last twenty years.
However, NSSO’s calorie data shows that at any given point in time the calorie intake
of the poorest quartile continues to be 30 to 50 percent less than the calorie intake of
the top quartile of the population, despite the poor needing more calories because of
harder manual work. The data also shows higher reliance of the poor on cereal based
calories because of lack of access to fruits, vegetables and meat products. Second,
daily calorie consumption of the bottom 25 per cent of the population has decreased
from 1,683 kcalories in 1987-88 to 1,624 kcalories in 2004-05. These figures should
be judged against a national norm of 2,400 and 2,100 kcalories/day for rural and
urban areas fixed by GOI in 1979. Similar downward trend is observed for cereal
consumption too. As the relative price of food items has remained stable over the past
twenty years, declining consumption can be attributed to the lack of purchasing power
and contraction of effective demand by the poor, who are forced to spend a greater

3

part of their limited incomes on non-food items like transport, fuel and light, health,
and education, which have become as essential as food.

Calorie intake refers to the most proximate aspect of hunger, but it neglects other
effects of hunger, such as being under-weight and mortality. These are captured by
the Global Hunger Index (GHI) which was designed by IFPRI based on three
dimensions of hunger: lack of economic access to food, shortfalls in the nutritional
status of children, and child mortality, which is to a large extent attributable to
malnutrition. IFPRI estimated the hunger index for India as 23 per cent in 2008,
which placed India in the category of nations where hunger was ‘alarming’, with
Madhya Pradesh being categorised as ‘extremely alarming’. Worse, its score was
poorer than many Sub-Saharan African counties, with a lower GDP than India’s.
This is primarily because of the fact that anthropometric indicators of the nutritional
status for children in India are among the worst in the world. According to the
National Family Health Survey, the proportion of underweight children remained
virtually unchanged between 1998-99 and 2005-06 (from 47 to 46 percent for the age
group of 0-3 years). These are appalling figures, which place India among the most
“undernourished” countries in the world.

Higher child malnutrition rate in India (for that matter in the entire South Asia) is
caused by many factors. First, Indian women’s nutrition, feeding and caring practices
for young children are inadequate. This is related to their status in society, early
marriage, low weight at pregnancy and their lower level of education. The proportion
of infants with a low birth weight in 2006 was as high as 30 per cent. Underweight
women produce low birth-weight babies which become further vulnerable to
malnutrition because of low dietary intake, lack of appropriate care, poor hygiene,
poor access to medical facilities, and inequitable distribution of food within the
household.
Second, many unscientific traditional practices still continue, such as delaying breast
feeding after birth, no exclusive breastfeeding for the first five months, irregular and
insufficient complementary feeding after between 6 months to two years of age, and
lack of disposal of child’s excreta because of the practice of open defecation in or
close to the house itself. Clearly government’s communication efforts in changing the
age old practices are not working well.
And lastly, poor supply of government services, such as immunisation, access to
medical care, and lack of priority to assigned primary health care in government
programmes also contributes to morbidity. These factors combined with poor food
availability in the family, unsafe drinking water and lack of sanitation lead to high
child under-nutrition and mortality. About 2.1 million deaths occur annually in under5 year-old children in India. Seven out of every 10 of these are due to diarrhoea,
pneumonia, measles, or malnutrition and often a combination of these conditions.

I

I
I

1.1 Policy recommendations
First, revamp small holder agriculture. Because of stagnating growth in agriculture
after the mid-1990s there has been employment decline, income decline and hence a
fall in aggregate demand by the rural poor. The most important intervention that is
needed is greater investment in irrigation, power, and roads in poorer regions. It is
essential to realize the potential for production surpluses in Central and Eastern India,
where the concentration of poverty is increasing.

■>

5

six times a day in appropriate quantities for the infant, which alone can improve the
infant’s nutrition levels. For nutrition to improve, we have to strengthen proper
breastfeeding and complementary feeding, together with complete immunisation and
prompt management of any illness.
Ninth, cover all adolescent girls under ICDS. They need to be graded according to
age, such as 10-15 group, 16-19 group and pregnant girls. Then they should be
weighed regularly, and given appropriate nutritious food containing all the desired
micro-nutrients and iron. Similar initiative is needed for all women.

Tenth, establish ICDS centres on priority within one year in all primitive tribal group
(PTG) settlements and the most discriminated Scheduled caste (SC) - previously the
untouchable people - settlements, without any ceiling of minimum children; and all
other hamlets with more than 50 per cent SC, ST, or minority populations within two
years. In all these centres, ICDS staff should be locals from the discriminated
communities, and two hot meals should be served instead of one to children aged 3 to
6 years; and weaning foods be given at least twice daily to children below 3 years.

Eleventh, prepare a comprehensive list every two years of all destitutes needing free
or subsidized cooked food. Open up mid-day meals kitchen to these old, destitutes
and hungry in the village. This is already being done in Tamil Nadu, and its
replication in other states should be funded by the GOI. Establish community kitchens
across cities and urban settlements to provide inexpensive, subsidised nutritious
cooked meals near urban homeless and migrant labour settlements.
Last, India requires is a significant increase of targeted investments in nutrition
programs, clinics, disease control, irrigation, rural electrification, rural roads, and
other basic investments, especially in rural India, where the current budgetary
allocations are inadequate. Higher public investments in these areas need to be
accompanied by systemic reforms that will overhaul the present system of service
delivery, including issues of control and oversight (Bajpai et al. 2005). Outlays should
not be considered as an end in itself. Delivery of food based schemes requires
increasing financial resources, but more importantly the quality of public expenditures
in these areas. This in turn requires improving the governance, productivity and
accountability of government machinery.
2 Understanding hunger
In the last decade and a half that India has successfully embraced economic reforms, a
curious problem has haunted the country and vexed its policy makers. India s
excellent growth has had little impact on food security1 and nutrition levels of its
population. Per capita availability as well as consumption of foodgrains has
decreased; cereal intake of the bottom 30 percent continues to be much less than the
cereal intake of the top two deciles of the population despite better access of the latter
group to fruits, vegetables and meat products; calorie consumption of the bottom half
of the population has been consistently decreasing since 1987; unemployment among
agricultural labour households has sharply increased from 9.5 per cent in 1993-94 to
15.3 per cent in 2004-05 (Planning Commission 2006); the percentage of underweight
children has remained stagnant between 1998 and 2006; and more than half of India s
women and three-quarters of children are anaemic with no decline in the last eight
1 The commonly accepted definition adopted at the 1996 World Food Summit is: Food security is
achieved when all people, at all times, have physical and economic access to sufficient, safe and
nutritious food to meet their dietary needs and food preferences for an active and healthy life.

6

years. In short, all indicators point to the hard fact that endemic hunger continues to
afflict a large proportion of Indian population. Internationally, India is shown to be
suffering from alarming hunger, ranking 66 out of the 88 developing countries studied
(IFPRI 2008). India as part of the world community has pledged to halve hunger by
2015, as stated in the Millennium Development Goal 1, but the present trends show
that this target is unlikely to be met.
This paper examines the hunger and nutrition situation prevailing in the country and
reviews the obligations and initiatives by the government of India (GOI) to ensure
food security through various policies and schemes.
Structure of the paper - In this section we look at various forms of hunger and make
a distinction between explicit hunger and chronic or endemic hunger that manifests
itself in the lower intake of essential calories, proteins, fats, and micro-nutrients
resulting in the under-development of the human mind and body. Section three
examines data, both from government and other sources on self-reported hunger. It
also discusses India’s record in improving its position on various indicators that are
generally used to measure hunger, such as calorie consumption, body mass index
(BMI), proportion of malnourished children, and child mortality.
The fourth section analyses various aspects of food security both at the micro- and
macro levels. The reasons for the decline in food consumption are analysed, followed
by a brief discussion on the recent global trend of reduced availability and increasing
prices. The fifth section is devoted to suggesting changes in some of the major
policies and programmes that affect food security; such as agricultural production,
public wage works, Public Distribution System, Midday Meals Scheme, and the
Integrated Child Development Services (ICDS) programme for improving child
malnutrition. This is followed by a brief report on the Supreme Court intervention on
hunger related matters, and then the paper ends with a discussion on accountability,
which is a cross-sectoral issue.
Types of hunger - There are essentially two types of hunger (Gopaldas 2006). The
first is overt (or raw) hunger, or the need to fill the belly every few hours. Hunger in
simple terms is the desire to consume food. It can also be termed as self-reported
hunger, whereby people judge their own ability to fulfil the physiological urge to
satisfy their hunger.
The second type of hunger occurs when the human body gets used to having less food
than necessary for healthy development, and after a while the body does not even
demand more food. If people have always eaten less than their needs, their bodies
adjust to less food in what is known as biostatis (Krishnaraj 2006). It is also possible
to fill up the stomach with non-nutritious food, which does not provide the required
calories or micro-nutrients2 like vitamins, iron, iodine, zinc, and calcium that are
required in tiny amounts. Another situation could be when the essential calories,
proteins, fats and micronutrients are not absorbed in the body due to ill-health and
poor hygiene. In all such cases hunger is not articulated.

The second kind of hunger may be termed as chronic or endemic hunger as this is not
felt, recognised or voiced by children or adults. Chronic hunger does not translate into
pangs of hunger, but into subtle changes in the way the human body develops. For
2 Deficiency of micro-nutrients is often referred to as hidden hunger. However, micro-nutrients do not
work unless the person is consuming sufficient calories through proper quantity of fat, protein, etc.

7

instance, an under-fed child may be underweight or stunted for his age, if not
consuming sufficient calories and fats. If the child is deficient in Vitamin A, he or she
will not be able to see properly at dusk (“night blindness ), and respiratory ailments
may also occur. In severe Vitamin A deficiency, the child may go totally blind. In the
case of iron-deficiency anaemia, the child will slow down both mentally and
physically, perform poorly in school and experience chronic tiredness. In the case of
iodine deficiency, there will be mental retardation. In its severe form, a goitrous lump
may grow at the base of the neck. Thus prolonged hunger means a predetermined
‘physiological requirement’ or ‘human potential’, defined in terms of norms for
calorie and other essential nutrients and growth standards is not reached.
Subjective hunger, or the first kind of hunger is a matter of articulation — people or
populations have to indicate in some fashion that they are going hungry. This means
there must be a state of not being hungry, so that the state of being hungry can be
recognised as such. What if, not having such a base level, they cannot recognise or
articulate hunger? What if they have always had less food than they need? If body
gets used to having less food than needed, then hunger may never be articulated. Self­
reported hunger is also difficult to measure, since perceptions of hunger differ from
one person to another. Therefore objective indicators offer a better measure for
hunger, such as calorie consumption, body mass index, stunting, lack of sufficient
variety in food intake, as it is perfectly possible to have a full belly and yet display
every symptom of under-nutrition.
There is a link between nutritional status or health and human effort and productivity.
Hunger affects the ability of individuals to work productively, think clearly, and resist
disease. Hunger may lead to low output and hence poor wages. Hunger is thus both
cause and effect of poverty. Hunger in India has gender and age dimensions too.
Women, children and the old people are less likely to get full nutritious meals needed
for their development. Half of the country’s women suffer from anaemia and maternal
under-nourishment, resulting in maternal mortality and underweight babies. There are
important seasonal variations in nutritional and health status depending on the cycle
of agricultural work. Hunger and starvation also have regional and geographical
dimensions. Tribal regions in India have higher incidence of food insecurity than the
non-tribal regions in the same state. Agriculture has brought uneven development
across regions and is characterized by low levels of productivity and the degradation
of natural resources in tribal areas, leading to low crop output and reduced gathering
from CPRs (Common Property Resources).
Hunger can also be equated with chronic food insecurity as both refer to a situation in
which people consistently consume diets inadequate in calories and essential
nutrients. This often happens due to the inability to 'access food for lack of
purchasing power. Destitution, leading in extreme cases to starvation deaths but in
any case to a life in misery, is more endemic amongst certain groups. These include
persons with disabilities, persons with stigmatizing illnesses such as leprosy or
HIV/AIDS, the elderly and the young who lack family support and single women.
Social and employment factors causing destitution include scheduled caste
population, tribal populations, manual scavengers, beggars, sex workers, landless
labourers and artisans. Persons displaced by natural disasters or development projects
are also often in this group. Due to prolonged deprivation of sufficient food and
recurring uncertainty about its availability these people are forced to lose their dignity
through foraging and begging, debt bondage and low end highly underpaid work, self

8

denial; and sacrifice of other survival needs like medicine or children’s education, and
thus they transfer their misery to the next generation (Mander 2008).
3

Dimensions of hunger

3.1 Self-reported hunger
Various NSSO3 rounds in India from 1983 onwards have statistically measured4 the
first type of hunger, by asking people on the availability of two square meals a day.
The results are shown in Table 1.
Table 1: Trend in self-reported hunger in India from 1983 to 2004-05

Year

Percentage of population reporting hunger
Rural

Urban

Total

18.54

6.33

16.1

1993-94

5.1

1.6

4.2

1999-00

3.3

0.9

2.6

2004-05

2.4

0.5

1.9

1983

Source: Kumaran 2008
Explicit hunger is especially severe in rural Orissa, West Bengal, Kerala, Assam and
Bihar. The non-availability of two square meals a day peaks in the summer months
from June to September with longer periods of suffering in West Bengal and Orissa
(Mehta and Shah 2002).
The data shows a drastic decline in self-reported hunger in India from 16.1 to 1.9
percent, which can be interpreted as a decline in food insecurity in its severest form,
while much was left undone on other fronts like food and nutritional insecurity in its
not so severe form. However how does one reconcile the above data with significant
reduction in cereal intake (see Table 16) over the years? Is that a result of declining
demand or sign of distress?
An Expert Group (GOI, 1993), while evaluating the suitability of using subjective
hunger data for inferring the extent of poverty arrived at two critiques which are
useful for the present context. First commenting on the limited reliability of the data
as an objective measure the Expert Group noted:
Tt has to be kept in mind that the information regarding the adequacy or inadequacy
of food for consumption, elicited through a single probing question, may not always
be free from subjectivity and at the same time may not be adequately precise and
objective. For instance the size of a 'square meal’ would differ not only from person to
person but also from place to place’ (GOI 1993:53).
3 The National Sample Survey Organisaton of the Ministry of Programme Implementation and
Statistics (GOI) conducts surveys on various socio-economic issues annually. The 61st round of the
National Sample Survey (NSS) conducted between July 2004 to June 2005 collected data on household
consumer expenditure on a large sample basis and was the seventh quinquennial survey on the subject.
It covered a sample of 79,298 rural and 45,346 urban households in all the states and union territories
of India.
4 In 1999-2000 and 2004-05 the question asked was, Do all members of your household get enough
food every day’? (NSSO 2007). In earlier surveys the responds were asked about the availability of two
square meals a day for their family members.

9

The second aspect, noted by the Expert Group, relates to the problem of relying on the
male head of households for the information on hunger experienced by other family
members.

‘Very often, particularly in rural India, the head of the family, usually a man, who is
the main respondent in the survey, would not be sufficiently aware of the quantity and
content of meal left for his wife and other female members of the house. Therefore,
this data would probably give only a broad idea about the perceptions of the people on
adequacy of food’ (GOI 1993:54).

There is yet another problem in interpreting the data given in Table 1. Often men, as
bread-winners would hate to admit that they cannot provide even two square meals to
their dependents (Kundu 2006: 120). Issues of pride, self-image and dignity are
involved here, which leads to a deep sense of shame and reluctance on the part of the
head of the households to publicly admit their inability to provide for their respective
families. This may result in under-reporting on the number of meals family members
are able to afford. For these reasons the NSSO data on decline in hunger over the
years cannot be relied upon.
In addition to NSSO, there have been other empirical studies on subjective hunger.
The Government of West Bengal conducted a rural household survey (Roy 2008) in
2006 through the panchayats and rural development department in which 3.5 per cent
of the population reported that they are not assured of even one meal a day. Another
16.5 per cent face difficulties arranging two square meals a day for all months in a
year. In all around 12 million rural people5 (around 2.5 million rural families) do not
get two square meals a day throughout the year.

A survey (UNDP 2007) was done in selected districts by Pratham, a voluntary
organization. The rural residents were asked on the number of meals they consumed
on most days in a year, and the number of clothes the young women in their families
possessed. The results are shown in the figure below.
Fig 1: Percentage of rural households who

70 1
60



50 -

40 J
30 1

20 "I

.A;A;7

m eat less than 2 meals a day

-♦-own less than 3 sets of
clothes

10 1
0

I 1111 ’ 11 n
This shows that the number of people consuming less than two meals a day varied
from 5 to 23 per cent in the rural areas of selected districts, whereas the number of
women having just one or two set of clothes was as high as 60 per cent in some
districts.
5 The total population of West Bengal in 2001 was 80 million.

10

A recent UNDP study (2008) selected 16 districts (9 backward and 7 non-backward)
from the backward states and conducted a perception study of households selected at
random in the districts. The finding on access to food is given in Table 2.
Table 2: District-wise distribution of households according to adequacy of access
to food
Highly
Average Some what
Some
Highly
District
State
Inadequate
Inadequate
what
Adequate
Adequate

Total

29.5

8?5

39.5

20.5

2

100

Dungarpur

2

4.5

65.5

25.5

2.5

100

Sitapur

8

24

10

49

9

100

Lalitpur

3.5

5

5.5

76.5

9.5

100

Azamgarh

6

15.5

21.5

41

16

100

Mandla

0.5

2

43.5

50.5

3.5

100

Tikamgarh

14

45.5

23.5

10.5

6.5

100

Gaya

4

16.5

23.5

46

10

100

Muzzafarpur

5.5

4

14

46

30.5

100

Pumia

4.5

3.5

16.5

49.5

26

100

Palamu

17.5

35

40.5

7

0

100

Dumka

12

41.5

37.5

9

0

100

Kanker

10

45

35.5

9.5

0

100

BilasPur

14

69

16

1

0

100

Ganjam

5.5

45

37.5

10

2

100

Keonjhar

2.5

36.5

40

18

3

100

Total

8.69

25.06

29.38

29.34

7.53

100

Number

278

802

940

939

241

3200

Rajasthan

Uttar Pradesh

Madhya
Pradesh

Bihar

Jharkhand
Chhattisgarh

Orissa

Barmer

Thus 7.5 per cent of respondents state that the access to food grains is highly
inadequate, and in about 29 per cent of the households it is somewhat inadequate. It is
only in about 9 per cent of the households which report that access to food grain is
considered highly adequate. However, the district-wise variations are very stark, more
than 76 per cent of the households in Lalitpur have somewhat inadequate access, but
the situation in Muzaffarpur appears very bad with nearly 31 per cent of the
households reporting highly inadequate access. This stresses the need for governance
and monitoring at the district level as very critical.

3.2

Measuring hunger by calorie consumption

Hunger has many faces: loss of energy, apathy, increased susceptibility to disease,
shortfalls in nutritional status, disability, and premature death. No single indicator can



11
provide a complete picture, and that a variety of different indicators should be used in
analysing different aspects of the problem. One needs to measure dietary diversity,
rather than just the consumption of food staples. Some aspects of hunger, such as the
stability of food consumption between seasons and between years, are generally not
captured by the existing data. In this paper we shall use several indicators - calorie
consumption, BMI, low weight and height among children, and anaemia among
women and children - to see how the situation has changed over the years in India.

In this section we focus on hunger-poverty, as measured by calorie deficiency caused by not consuming the energy required by the body. The mean per capita
consumption of calories, protein, and fats as calculated by Deaton and Dreze (2008)
for various NSS rounds is shown below:

Table 3: Mean per capita consumption of calories, protein, and fats.
Fats (gms)
Protein (gms)
Calories (kc)
Urban
Rural
Urban
Urban Rural
Round Rural
Year
37.1

60.3

27/r
MF
58.6
FTF 3TT

59.1“

58.4

36.0

49.6

2,027

w

MF

346“

46.1 “

2,018

1j82“

■54F

■542“

33.6

FT

2,025

2,014

55.4

347“

47.0

2,106

2,020’

58.0

2004 “ "60

^087

"X036" MF

MF
MF
MF

35.5

46.8

2004-5 “61

F047

“^021"

55.4

35.4

47.4 ’

1983

38

2,240

2,070

MF

1987-8

43

2,233

2>5"

63.2

1993-4

50

2j53“

X073"

1999- 0 55
2000- T 56
2001- 2 57
38
2002
■59
2003

2,148

2,155

2,083

55.8“

58.1

39.3
41.9

MF

Thus, in spite of India’s rapid economic growth, there has been a sustained decline in
per capita calorie and protein consumption during the last twenty-five years; fats are
the only major nutrient group whose per capita consumption is unambiguously
increasing. Patnaik (2007) points out that during the same period the calorie intake in
below poverty line households also declined. The calorie intake at poverty line was
2,170 kcal in 1977-78, 2,060 kcal in 1983, 1,980 kcal in 1993-94 and 1820 kcal in
2004-05.
The decline in calorie consumption of the top quartile could be due to more sedentary
life style or to increasing diversity in food intake, but the decline for the bottom
quartile since 1987, as shown in Table 4, cannot be interpreted as a sign of prosperity.
Several inferences can be drawn from Table 4. First, at any given point in time the
calorie intake of the poorest quartile continues to be 30 to 50 percent less than the
calorie intake of the top quartile of the population, despite the poor needing more
calories because of harder manual work. Second, calorie consumption of the bottom
fifty per cent of the population has been consistently descreasing since 1987, which is
a matter of concern. And last, whereas the top quartile derived only 58 per cent
calories from cereals in 2004-05, the bottom quartile still depended on cereals for 78
per cent of its calorie consumption.

12
Table 4: Total and cereal calorie consumption by decile and quartile of per
capita expenditure, rural India, 1983 to 2004-05 (figures in kcal)

Top
Bottom Bottom Second Third
Quartile Quartile Quartile Quartile
decile

Total calories
1,359
1983
1987-88 1788
1993-94 1,490

1,580

2,007

2,328

3,044

^683

2,056

2,334

2,863

1,659

Xooo

2,251

2,702

1999-00 T796
2004-05 1785

L658

1,978

2^50

2?707

1,624

X900

2,143

2,521

1,150

1,309

1,589

1,738

1,974

U2T

1,359

1,598

1,715

1,894

1,203

1,316

1,504

1,591

1,690

1J97

1,289

1,591

1,509

1,566

2004-05 U89

h259

1,690

1730

1,471
Source: Deaton and Dreze 2008

Cereal calories

1983
1987-88
1993-94
1999-00

A similar picture, of the wide gap between the consumption of the bottom 30 per cent
and top 30 per cent, as well as falling calorie consumption over time of all groups
including the lower 30 per cent, emerges when one looks at variation for a longer
period since 1972-73, as shown in figure 2.
Figure 2: time trends in average per capita energy intake by expenditure classes

3500 -1
3200 2900 15 2600 £ 23002000 1700 1400 -

*

72-73



77-78

Rural Lower 30%

93-94

99-2000 2004-05

—«— Rural Middle 40%
Urban Lower 30^/o

J
(Ramachandran 2007)

Another study on hunger (Ahmed et al. 2007) based on the same NSSO data
disaggregated those consuming fewer than 2,200 kcal in India into three groups:

• Subjacent hungry: those consuming more than 1,800 but fewer than 2,200 kcal a day
• Medial hungry: those consuming more than 1,600 but fewer than 1,800 kcal a day

• Ultra hungry: those consuming less than 1,600 kcal a day

13
The study found that in all 58 per cent people in India suffered from hunger in 1999,
of which 17.4 per cent were classified as ultra hungry.

Table 5: Incidence of Hunger in India (1999)
National

Rural

Urban

Subjacent hungry

20

28.9

27.9

Medial hungry

12.1

12.1

12.3

Ultra hungry

17.4

17.1

18.0

Total

58.1

58.1

58.3

3.2.1

How many calories are needed for healthy living?

The calculation of calorie norms or requirements is complicated as the daily calorie
requirement for healthy life is a function of age, sex and nature of work. The required
average for the entire society will decline if rising incomes lead to a shift from manual
to sedentary life style, but would go up if the proportion of working age population
increases as indeed is happening in India due to demographic changes. In the absence
of well accepted norms of calorie consumption for different time periods valid for
India it is difficult to come to any definite conclusion about the percentage of
population that is not able to satisfy the minimum required calorie needs for healthy
living in a particular year.
The Planning Commission constituted a ‘Task Force on Projection of Minimum
Needs and Effective Consumption Demand’ which on the basis of a systematic study
of nutritional requirements recommended (GOI 1979) a national norm of 2,400 kilo
calories/day and 2,100 kilo calories/day for rural and urban areas (the difference bem^
attributed to the lower rates of physical activity in the urban areas) respectively .
These figures were derived from age-sex-occupation-specific nutritional norms by
using the all-India demographic data from the 1971 Census. However, these have not
been revised, and hence the confusion in interpreting subsequent data based on old
norms of calorie consumption.
There is yet another problem in interpreting calorie data, when it is disaggregated to
the Indian states. The diet of people in poorer states, such as Assam, Orissa and Bihar,
is not diversified and they eat more cereals compared to Kerala and Tamil Nadu
where diets include more vegetables, fats, and fish. The result is that per capita calorie
consumption is higher in Orissa and Bihar but in the absence of proteins and essential
fats these states report higher malnutrition than Kerala and Tamil Nadu, as shown in
column 3 of Table 9. Therefore calorie consumption cannot be the sole determinant of
hunger. Because of these problems Deaton and Dreze (2008) concluded that, there is
no tight link between the numbers of calories consumed and nutritional or health
status. Although the number of calories is important, so are other factors, such as a
balanced diet containing a reasonable proportion of fruits, vegetables, and fats, not
just calories from cereals, as are factors that affect the need for and retention of

6 The average calorie norm of 2,110 kcal per capita per day prescribed by the FAO for South Asia
(Bajpai et al. 2005) in the eighties is much lower than the 2,400 kcal norm that has been typically used
by government in India. The latest calorie norm used by FAO for India is 1820 kcal (IFPRI 2008).

14
calories, such as activity levels, clean water, sanitation, good hygiene practices, and
vaccinations.’

The MDGs call for halving of hunger-poverty between 1990 and 2015. Assuming
constant norms of 2400/2100 kcalories for India, this would mean bringing down the
headcount ratio of calorie deficiency from 62.2 per cent in 1990 to 31.1 per cent in
2015. However, the number of people below the norm has consistently increased over
the years, and more than three quarters of the population live in households whose per
capita calorie consumption is less than the norm, as shown in Table 6.

Table 6: Fractions of the population living in households with per capita calorie
consumption below 2,100 kcal in urban and 2,400 kcal in rural areas

Round Rural Urban All India

Year

1983

38

66.1

60.5

64.8

1987-8

43

65.9

57.1

63.9

1993-4

50

71.1

67.8

1999-0

55

74.2

58.1
58.2

70.1

2004-5

61

79.8

63.9

75.8
(Deaton and Dreze 2008)

The mere consumption of an adequate number of calories may not ensure sufficient
intake of other nutrients, such as proteins, fats and micro-nutrients, which are just as
essential for human health. It can further be argued that there is a distinction between
gross calorie intake and net calorie absorption, and that the relationship between the
two may change over time depending upon the incidence and severity of gastro­
intestinal disorders.
Table 7: Percentage of the undernourished population in India below the
threshold levels of protein and fat, 1983 and 1999-2000
Upper Group
Bottom Group
Year

Rural

Urban

All India

Rural

Urban

All India

1983"

51

64

55

9

20

13

1999-00"

65

65

65

14

"14

14

198?

61

40

55

10

4

8

1999-00

48

16

36

“4

I

T

Protein

Fats

(Kumar et al. 2007)

Notes: Bottom group: Below poverty line; Upper group: Above 150 per cent of
poverty line
Table 7 reveals a general decrease in protein consumption, particularly in the bottom
income group in irural
---- areas7,, where the .population below threshold level had
7 The sample households were grouped into poor (bottom) and non-poor (upper) classes. The non-poor
class comprised households which were above 150 per cent of the poverty line, whereas, the poor class

15

increased from 51 per cent to 65 per cent in terms of protein intake. Ideally, the source
of protein should be pulses and meat. But the data showed that cereals contributed 67
per cent of the protein consumed in rural India. It can perhaps be explained in terms
of the lack of purchasing power for procuring an adequate quantity of high-value non­
cereal commodities to compensate for loss in nutrition owing to replacement of
cereals.
To conclude this section, there is strong evidence of a sustained decline in per-capita
calorie and protein consumption in India during the last twenty five years. The
proportionate decline was larger among better-off sections of the population, but also
existed for the bottom quartile of the per-capita expenditure scale. While calorie
deficiency is an extremely important aspect of nutritional deprivation, close attention
needs to be paid to other aspects of food deprivation, such as the intake of vitamins
and minerals, fat consumption, the diversity of the diet, and breastfeeding practices.
3.2.2 The official poverty line
The national-level official poverty lines for the base year (1973-74) were expressed as
monthly per capita consumption expenditure of Rs 49 in rural areas and Rs 57 in
urban areas, which corresponded to a basket of goods and services that satisfy the
calorie norms of per capita daily requirement of 2400 kcal in rural areas and 2100
kcal in urban areas. These figures have been updated for price rises for the subsequent
years. However, the new poverty lines do not correspond to the minimum calorie
norm* as the poor have been forced to shift their priorities to essential non-food items.
Therefore for the year 1999-00 the monetary cut-off corresponding to the minimum
calorie requirements norms should have been Rs 565 in rural areas and Rs 628 in
urban areas, whereas by the price updated methodology as used by Planning
Commission the poverty line was Rs 328 and Rs 454 respectively. The current va ue
of the poverty line does not permit the poverty line class to consume the calorific
norm, and the periodic price corrections that have been carried out to update the
poverty lines are inadequate and indeed may be even inappropriate (Sen 2005).
Consequently, the poverty estimates made in the years after 1973-74 understate the
true incidence of poverty in the country. There is a compelling case for re-estimating
the poverty lines. The proportion of people living below the official poverty line
declined from 56 per cent in 1973-74 to 35 per cent in 1993-94, and further to 28 per
cent in 2004-05, whereas there has been no decline in the number of people
consuming less calories than the norm (Table 6). The set of food insecure in India is
larger than the set of poor in India.
Several features of poverty in India stand out. First, poverty is being concentrated in
the poorer states. In terms of absolute numbers, Uttar Pradesh, Bihar and Jharkhand
account for around 27 per cent of the country’s population but 30 per cent of India’s
poor lived there in 1973-74, which has increased to over 41 per cent by 2005
(Himanshu 2007). Second, more than three-fourths of the poor live in rural areas.
Third, more than three-fourths of the rural poor depend on agriculture. Agricultural
growth will therefore have greatest potential of poverty reduction.
Fourth, poverty has many social dimensions. There has been hardly any decline in
poverty for the Scheduled Tribe households, almost half of them continue to be below
consisted of households below the poverty line. The poverty line for rural and urban areas in different
states corresponding to various NSS rounds, as defined and adopted by the Planning Commission, was
used in the study.



16
the poverty line. Although poverty among the Scheduled Castes has declined from 46
to 37 per cent during 1993-2004 (Planning Commission 2008), the caste system
confines those from lower castes to a limited number of poorly paid, often socially
stigmatised occupational niches from which there is little escape, except by migrating
to other regions or to towns where their caste identity is less well known. Many states,
especially in the north and western part of the country, are characterised by long­
standing and deeply entrenched social inequalities associated with gender. Gender
cuts across class, leading to deprivations and vulnerabilities which are not necessarily
associated with household income.

And lastly, poverty is intimately connected with vulnerability and shocks. Severe and
chronic deprivation in India is compounded by general uncertainty with respect to
livelihood and life, which threatens an even wider section of the population than
might be counted as poor.

Thus poverty is an extremely complex phenomenon, which manifests itself in a range
of overlapping and interwoven economic, political and social deprivations. These
include lack of assets, low income levels, hunger, poor health, insecurity, physical and
psychological hardship, social exclusion, degradation and discrimination, and political
powerlessness and disarticulation. Therefore, policy instruments should be designed
to address not only the low income and consumption aspect of poverty, but also the
more complex social dimensions (Sen and Himanshu 2004).
The existing types of poverty programmes may not be enough to tackle hunger and
food insecurity. Important food security issues are often left out of poverty
programmes, such as the stability of food consumption, dietary diversity, and food
absorption and utilisation. Furthermore, poverty programmes may fail to recognise
how hunger and malnutrition impair people's capacity to participate in productive
activities and result in worse school performance. Hence there is a need to mainstream
hunger in the existing programmes.

3.3 IFPRI’s composite index on hunger
Calorie intake refers to the most proximate aspect of hunger, but it neglects other
effects of hunger, such as under-weight and mortality. These are captured by the
Global Hunger Index (GHI) that was designed to capture three dimensions of hunger:
lack of economic access to food, shortfalls in the nutritional status ot children, and
child mortality, which is to a large extent attributable to malnutrition (Wiesmann et al.
2007). Accordingly, the Index includes the following three equally weighted
indicators: the proportion of people who are food-energy deficient according to the
Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO ) estimates, the
proportion of children under the age of five who are underweight according to the
World Health Organization estimates, and the under-five mortality rate as estimated
by UNICEF.
The Global Hunger Index recognizes the interconnectedness of these dimensions, and
therefore captures performance on all the three of them. The index has been an
effective advocacy tool which has brought the issue of global and national hunger to
the fore in policy debates, especially in developing countries. The ranking of nations
on the basis of their index scores has been a powerful tool to help focus attention on
8 According to FAO, after seeing a decline of 20 million in the number of undernourished between
1990-1992 and 1995-1997, the number of hungry people in India increased from 201.8 million in
1995-1997 to 212.0 million in 2001-2003.

17

hunger, especially for countries like India which under-perform on hunger and
malnutrition relative to their income levels.
IFPRI estimated9 that the hunger index for India had declined from 34 per cent in
1990 to 23 per cent in 2008, although India still continued to be in the category of
nations where hunger was ‘alarming’. Worse, its score was poorer than many SubSaharan African counties, which have a lower GDP than India’s. This indicates
continued poor performance at reducing hunger in India.

Table 8: GDP per capita in relation to scores on the Global Hunger Index 2008
Country

GHI2008

GDP per Capita1
nnp

1977“
Nigeria
18.4
18.7
2124
Cameroon
19.9
1535
Kenya
20.5
2088
Sudan
23.7
2753
India
Gross Domestic Product (GDP) dollar estimates at Purchasing Power Parity (PPP)
per capita Source: World Development Indicators, 2007 (World Bank)
A recent IFPRI report (2008) estimated hunger index for 17 major states in India,
covering more than 95 percent of the population of India, shown in Table 9. All 17
states have GHI scores that are well above the “low” and “moderate” hunger
categories. Twelve of the 17 states fall into the “alarming” category, and one Madhya Pradesh - into the “extremely alarming” category. The study concluded that
GHI scores are closely aligned with poverty, but there is little association with state
level economic growth. High levels of hunger are seen even in states that are
performing well economically, such as Gujarat and Karnataka.
3.4 BMI
A widely used measure of nutritional status is a combination of weight and height
measurements known as the Body Mass Index (BMI). Low body weight, associated
with low intakes, is an indication that people could not reach their growth potential
and hence is essentially a sign of continued hunger and nutritional distress. This is
defined as weight in kilogrammes divided by height in metre squared. A BMI of
below 18.5 for adults indicates chronic energy deficiency (CED), which would be due
to an intake of calories and other nutrients less than the requirement for a period of
several months or years.
According to the XI Plan, volume 2 (Planning Commission 2008), in 1998-99 as
much as 36 per cent of the adult population of India had a body mass index (BMI)
below 18.5; eight years later (2005—06) that share had barely fallen to 33 per cent of
the population, despite a decade of robust economic growth. These figures are based
on the NFHS data, which is collected from all the states. Changes in BMI are also
9 IFPRI used a cut-off of 1,632 kcals per person per day as the national calorie under-nutrition norm
which showed 20 per cent calorie deficient people in India. FAO has also used the norm of 1632 kcal,
showing a reduction in the number of under-nounshed population from 25 to 20 per cent during 19902005. Had it used 1,820 kcals per person per day as the cut-off the number of under-nourished
population in 2005 would have been 34 per cent.

18
monitored by the National Nutrition Monitoring Bureau (NNMB, shown in Table 10),
but it covers only ten10 states.
Table 9: Underlying components of India State Hunger Index and India State
Hunger Index scores
percentage
India
India State
Under-five
Prevalenc Proportio
State
of people
Hunger
Hunger
n
of
mortality
e of
below
Index
Index
score
rate,
calorie underwei
poverty
line
Ranking
ght
underreported as
in
2004-05
among
deaths per
nourishm
hundred
ent children<
5years
2

T

4

5

India

20.0

42.5

7.4

23.31

Andhra Pradesh

19.6

32.7

6.3

19.54

3

15.79

Assam

14.6

36.4

8.5

19.85

4

19.73

Bihar

17.3

56.1

8.5

27.30

15

41.35

Chhattisgarh

23.3

47.6

9.0

26.65

14

40.88

Gujarat

23.3

44.7

6.1

24.69

13

16.75

Haryana

15.1

39.7

5.2

20.01

5

14.03

Jharkhand

19.6

57.1

9.3

28.67

16

40.35

Karnataka

28.1

37.6

5.5

23.74

11

24.98

Kerala

28.6

22.7

1.6

17.66

2

15.04

Madhya
Pradesh

23.4

59.8

9.4

30.90

17

38.29

Maharashtra

27.0

36.7

4.7

22.81

10

30.75

Orissa

21.4

40.9

9.1

23.79

12

46.37

Punjab

11.1

24.6

5.2

13.64

1

8.41

Rajasthan

14.0

40.4

8.5

20.99

7

22.06

Tamil Nadu

29.1

30.0

3.5

20.88

6

22.53

Uttar Pradesh

14.5

42.3

9.6

22.17

9

32.81

West Bengal

18.5

38.5

5.9

21.00

8

24.72

1

I

6

7

27.5

(IFPRI 2008)

10 Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka, Kerala, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, Madhya Pradesh, Orissa, Uttar
Pradesh, Gujarat, and West Bengal

19
Table 10: Nutrition status of Indian adults, 1975-9 to 2004-5 (Body Mass Index)
per cent decline
Proportion ( per cent) of adults with BMI below 18.5

1975-79

1988-90

1996-97

2000-01

2004-05

Men

56

49

46

37

33

Women

52

49

48

39

36

(1975-9 to 2004-5)
41
31

(Deaton and Dreze 2008)

Predictably the percentage of women in rural areas with BMI below 18.5 in 2004-05
was 41.2 according to NNMB, which is twice that among urban women 22.7 (Arnold
et al. 2004). Regarding age distribution, the percentage of women with BMI below
18.5 ranges from 41.7 for the age group 15-19 to 43.2 for 20-24, 39.4 for 25-29, 35.1
for 30-34 and 31.1 for 35-49. Ironically, at the most vulnerable ages when their
reproductive demands are highest women are most deficient. So much for this
country’s esteem for mothers!
The data for each social group is available for 1996-97, shown below:

Table 11: Percentage of population with BMI < 18.5

Overall

47

Scheduled castes

53.2

Scheduled tribes

60.9

Others

46.8
(Sen 2004)

Undemutrition was relatively higher among the lower socio-economic category of
households such as those belonging to SC and ST communities.
A 20 year trend (Sen 2004) based on a large number of studies and the NNMB
surveys of Indians (1977-1996) show that there have been minimal improvements in
the weights of populations (of the same age) in India. The mean weight of children at
five years of age in 1977 was 12.7 kg and 14.1 kg (girls and boys); when compared to
the NCHS (US National Centre for Health Statistics) median weights of 17.7 kg and
18.7 kg, this deficit is of about 4 kg at the age of five. This increased to a deficit of 14
kg and 23 kg by the age of 18, and the mean weights of Indian women and men were
a mere 42.3 kg and 45.4 kg compared to the NCHS standard of 56.6 kg and 68.9 kg.
There was a small improvement in the weights of Indians as they reached the age of
25 (42.8 kg and 49.9 kg), but it was still way below their desirable weight. At and
above the age of 60 they slipped back to mean weights of 39.7 and 47.6 kg. By the
year 1996 the nutritional status of a large number of people had not changed, or
perhaps had improved only marginally. After observing a average weight gain of 1.25
kg to 2.5 kg at each age group, the author notes that these are mean weights, and
approximately half the population in India has lower weights than these (weights as
low as 38 kg) for adults, a condition very close to chronic energy deficiency or
starvation’ (Shatrugna 2001:2). Fast economic growth did not help these people to
gain a significant amount of height or weight.
Similarly, Shatrugna found that the average height of children from 1977 to 1996
increased minimally by 1 cm. Comparing the weight and height gain in high income
groups in India, the author noted that there was a clear potential for improving height

20

and weight of the Indian population as reflected by the considerable weight gain by
high income groups, captured by the field studies. However there is a huge gap
between actual and potential weight and height of the average Indian. In other words,
the under-nutrition is still forcing generations to remain stunted and remain thin, so
they cannot engage in hard work, given the low level of their food intake.

3.5

Undernourished children

Just as for adults, for children too, the anthropometric indicators of nutritional status
in India are among the worst in the world. According to the National Family Health
Survey, the proportion of underweight children remained virtually unchanged
between 1998-99 and 2005-06 (from 47 per cent to 46 per cent for the age group of 03 years). These are appalling figures, placing India among the most undernourished
countries in the world. The overall levels of child under-nutrition in India (including
not only severe but also moderate under-nourishment) are shown in Table 12.

Table 12: Trends in Child Nutrition: NFHS Data

Proportion (percentage) of children under the age of
three years who are undernourished
New WHO Standards
NCHS 11 Standards

1992-3

1W9 2005-6

1998-9

2005-6

Weight-for-age
Below 2 SD12

52

47.0

45.9

42.7

40.4

Below 3 SD

20

To

n/a

TT6

To

Below 2 SD

n/a

45.5

38.4

51.0

44.9

Below 3 SD

n/a

20

n/a

rTn

20

Below 2 SD

n/a

15.5

19.1

19.7

22.9

Below 3 SD

n/a

T8

n/a

“6?7

“O

Height-for-age

Weight-for-height

The data for children under five in 2005-2006 is similar to the above,

percentage of under-fives suffering from: underweight, moderate and
severe
percentage of under-fives suffering from: underweight, severe

43

percentage of under-fives suffering from: wasting, moderate and severe

20

percentage of under-fives (suffering from: stunting, moderate and severe

48

16

11 Until 2006, the World Health Organization (WHO) recommended the US National Centre for Health
Statistics (NCHS) standard, and this was used inter alia in the first and second rounds of the National
Family Health Survey. In April 2006, the WHO released new standards based on children around the
world (Brazil, Ghana, India, Norway, Oman, and the United States) who are raised in healthy
environments, whose mothers do not smoke, and who are fed with recommended feeding practices.
These new standards were used in the third National Family Health Survey.

12 Standard deviation

21

source: http://www.unicef.org/infobycountry/india statistics.html
Over 70 to 80% of the calories consumed by the children (even though inadequate)
are derived from cereals and pulses. This results in two things: (i) Children cannot
consume more cereals to make up for the calorie deficiency because of its sheer
monotony and lack of energy density, (ii) In the absence of fats, milk, eggs, and
sources of iron, children starve themselves nutritionally. The resultant iron deficiency
anaemia (IDA) further worsens their appetite. Therefore in the absence of foods other
than cereals and pulses in the diets of children and the inability of children in the age
group 1-18 years to derive and satisfy their protein-calorie and other nutrient needs,
the malnutrition scenario can only get worse. Even fats that provide energy density in
the diets are not available in adequate quantities (normally fats should provide 3040% of calorie needs). It is therefore not surprising that there is massive hunger
leading to multiple nutrient deficiencies. This is not hidden hunger; it is hunger for
nutrient rich foods (Planning Commission 2008).
The main reason that explains a higher child malnutrition rate in India (for that matter
in the entire South Asia) than in poorer, conflict-plagued Sub-Saharan Africa is that
Indian women’s nutrition, feeding and caring practices for young children are
inadequate. This is related to their status in society, early marriage, low weight at
pregnancy and their lower level of education. The percentage of infants with low birth
weight in 2006 was as high as 30. Underweight women produce low birth-weight
babies which become further vulnerable to malnutrition because of low dietary intake,
lack of appropriate care, poor hygiene, poor access to medical facilities, and
inequitable distribution of food within the household.
Estimates based on available data from institutional deliveries and smaller
community-based studies suggest that even now nearly one-third of all Indian infants
weigh less than 2.5 kg at birth. Studies (Ramachandran 2007) have shown that LBW
children have a low trajectory for growth in infancy and childhood.

Indian mothers on average put on barely 5 kg of weight during pregnancy. This is a
fundamental reason underlying the LBW problem. They should put on at least 10 kg
of weight, which is the average for a typical African woman (Planning Commission
2008). Middle class Indian women tend to put on well over 10 kg weight during
pregnancy. But this is not the only problem; LBW is also partly explained by low
BMI of women in general, prior to their becoming pregnant. Small women (who are
small before they become pregnant) give birth to small babies.
Even worse is the story about the number of anaemic children, whose percentage
during 1998-2006 has gone up from 74 per cent to 79 per cent.
Table 13: Levels of anaemia among Indian children (as percentage of the total)

Children
aged 635
months
who are
anaemic

NFHS-3 (2005-06)

NFHS-2 (1998-99)
All
India

Urban

Rural

Rural
Urban
Ratio

All
India

Urban

Rural

Rural
Urban
Ratio

74

71

75

fl

79

73

81

TT

(Kumar 2007)

22
When one looks at the Indian states, unlike calorie consumption which is only weakly
correlated with poverty, child malnutrition has a strong correlation with poverty (see
Table 9), with poorer states such as Madhya Pradesh, Bihar and Jharkhand showing a
high degree of malnutrition, whereas better-off states such as Punjab, Haryana, Tami
Nadu and Kerala show comparatively better performance on this indicator.
Determinants of Indian children’s malnourishment can be broadly divided into two
categories. In the first list are factors such as the irrational traditional practices that
still continue, not immediately starting breast feeding after birth, not exclusively
breastfeeding for the first five months, irregular and insufficient complementary
feeding after between 6 months to two years of age, and lack of disposal of child s
excreta because of the practice of open defecation in or close to the house itself
NFHS-3 data shows that 21 per cent of mothers dispose of their children s stoo
safely. There is wide variation between urban and rural households. Whereas 47.2 per
cent urban mothers did so, this proportion was only 11.4 for rural mothers. Clearly the
government’s communication efforts in changing age old practices are not working
well and
and critical
critical public
public health
health messages
messages are simply not reaching the families with
well,
children.
In the second category are factors relating to poor supply of government services,
such as immunisation, access to medical care, and lack of Pnon^
to
primary health care in government programmes. Table 14, based on NFHS-o results,
gives data on both, child rearing practices and government delivery.

Table 14: Access to and Reach of Basic Health Services for children 2005-06
-------------------------- -

Urban Rural

Total

Children under three years breastfed within one hour of birth

IT

29

22

Children aged 0-five months exclusively breastfed

46

40

48

Children aged six to nine months receiving solid or semi-solid
food and breastmilk
Children aged 12-23 months fully immunised (BCG, measles
and three doses each of polio/DPT)
Children aged 12-35 months who received a vitamin A dose m
last six months
Children with diarrhoea in the last 2 weeks who received ORS

56

62

54

44

58

39

21

23

20

26

33

24

Children with diarrhoea in the last 2 weeks taken to a health

58

65

56

51

74

43

22

35

18

facility
Mothers who had at least three antenatal care visits for their last
birth
Mothers who consumed IF A (a vitamin A supplement tablet) for
90 days or more when they were pregnant with their last child

(Kumar 2007)

13 This however is changing with the introduction of NRHM (National Rural Health Mission) in
.
Early evaluation results show optimistic progress in institutional delivery, new household toilets, and
creation of infrastructure for primary health care.

23

Despite the importance of breastfeeding and appropriate feeding for preventing
malnutrition, only 23 per cent of children under three years were breastfed within one
hour of birth and less than half the babies (46 per cent) aged 0-5 months were
exclusively breastfed. Equally striking is the low proportion of children of 6-9 months
-56 per cent - who received solid or semi-solid food and breast milk. It is well
known that frequent illnesses during early childhood and failing to treat them properly
seriously affects the nutritional well-being of children. With only one exception,
namely, children aged 0-5 months being exclusively breastfed, all other indicators
reveal lower reach and access to health services and care in rural areas compared to
urban areas. And this partially explains the higher levels of under-nourishment in
rural compared to urban areas. Also affecting the health and nutritional well-being of
children is the status of women’s health and their access to maternal care services.
Inter-state differences: By and large, in the four states with the lowest proportion of
underweight children — Punjab, Kerala, Jammu and Kashmir and Tamil Nadu —
provisioning of health services, the care of children especially newborns and the
nutritional status of women are better than in the four high malnutrition states of
Chhattisgarh, Bihar, Jharkhand and Madhya Pradesh.
For instance, the proportion of fully immunised children varied between 60 and 81 per
cent in the low malnutrition states and between 33 and 49 per cent in the high
malnutrition states. In the low malnutrition states, between 73 and 97 per cent of
mothers received at least three antenatal care visits; this proportion varied between 17
and 55 per cent in the high malnutrition states. And whereas 14-24 per cent of women
in the low malnutrition states have a BMI below normal, the proportion varied from
40-43 per cent in the high malnutrition states. There are, however, some exceptions
that need more careful examination. Chhattisgarh and Jharkhand seem to be doing
much better in their efforts to promote exclusive breastfeeding in the initial years of a
child’s life. 82 per cent of children aged 0-5 months in Chhattisgarh and 58 per cent m
Jharkhand are exclusively breastfed whereas in the low malnutrition states, the highest
proportion is 56 per cent in Kerala. Also, it is disturbing to find that Gujarat ranks
among the top five states reporting the highest proportion of underweight children - a
phenomenon that needs a closer examination.
The proportion of fully immunised children during 1998-99 to 2005-06 has declined,
in eight states - Andhra Pradesh, Gujarat, Himachal Pradesh, Karnataka, Kerala,
Maharashtra, Punjab and Tamil Nadu - these are generally regarded as more
prosperous than other states. On the other hand, immunisation coverage rates have
shown a significant improvement in West Bengal, Bihar, Jharkhand and Chhattisgarh.

On the whole, children’s access to certain critical components of treatment of
childhood diseases has declined over the past seven years. For instance, the proportion
of children with diarrhoea who received ORS in the two weeks preceding the survey
had risen from 18 per cent in 1992-93 to 27 per cent in 1998-99; but since then it has
fallen to 26 per cent in 2005-06.
The contrast between India and China14 is also of some interest in this context. There
is evidence of a steady growth in the heights of Chinese children in recent decades,
not only during the period of fast economic growth that followed the “economic
reforms” of the late 1970s, but also before that. For instance in a representative
sample of Chinese children aged 2-5 years, the average increase in height between
14 This para is based on Deaton and Dreze 2008

24

1992 and 2002 was 3 cm in rural areas (for both boys and girls), and even higher in
urban areas (3.6 cm and 3.8 cm for boys and girls, respectively). According to an
earlier study, the average heights of Chinese children between the ages of 7 and 14
years increased by approximately 8.04 cm between 1951-8 and 1979. NNMB data
suggests much slower growth rates for the heights of Indian children. The increase in
children’s heights between 1975-9 and 2004-5 was a little below 2 cm per decade at
age 3, and barely 1 cm per decade at age 5. The NNMB data also suggests that the
growth rates of heights and weights were particularly slow in the later part of this
period, with, for instance, very little growth in the heights of children at age 5
between 1996-7 and 2004-5.

3.6

Women 9s malnutrition15

According to NFHS-3, while more than one-third of women suffer from CED during
2005-06, over half the women in the age group of 15-49 years suffer from iron
deficiency anaemia. The incidence of anaemia among pregnant women is even higher,
nearly 59 per cent.
The implications of women’s malnutrition for human development are multiple and
cumulative. Women’s malnutrition tends to increase the risk of maternal mortality.
Maternal short stature and iron deficiency anaemia, which increase the risk of death of
the mother at delivery, account for at least 20 per cent of maternal mortality.
Additionally, maternal malnutrition impinges significantly on such important but
interconnected aspects as intrauterine growth retardation, child malnutrition and the
rising emergence of chronic diseases, among others.
Why has malnutrition been so high among women in India? The reasons are multiple
and complex. Apparently, the discriminatory practices associated with the rigid social
norms and the excessive demands made on the time and energies of women join
hands with the usual determinants in blighting women’s nutrition. However, one ot
the usual determinants, namely poverty, seems equally important: not only is poverty
one of the basic causes of malnutrition, but also malnutrition is considered to be both
an outcome and a manifestation of poverty.
Table 15 gives the data for women’s nutrition for various social and economic groups,
suggesting huge socio-economic disparities.
Thus nearly 47 and 68 per cent of women aged 15-49 years from the scheduled tribes
suffer from CED and anaemia, respectively. What is more, more than one-third of
them suffer from the double burden of CED and anaemia together. The incidence o
malnutrition declines with the so-called rise in social status. By extension, such
decline also means huge disparities between social groups: more than 15 percentage
points difference exists between women from ST and others. Thus, the proportion of
women suffering from CED and anaemia together among ST comes closer to double
the proportion of the same among advantaged social groups. More than 50 and 64 per
cent of women from the poorest quintile suffer from CED and anaemia, respectively.
Also, about one-third of them suffer from the double disadvantage of CED and
anaemia As we have observed among social groups, malnutrition among women goes
down drastically with a rise in the household wealth status, creating an equally large
disparity between the wealth groups. The proportion of the poorest women suffering

15 This section is based on Jose and Navaneetham 2008.

25
from CED and anaemia together comes around to more than three times that found in
the highest quintile.
Table 15: Women’s nutrition for social and economic groups (in percentage)

CED

CED and Anaemia

Anaemia

Both

Either I

Neither

Social groups
ST

46.6

68.5

33.5

47.8

18.7

SC

41.1

583”

ITT

47.7

262

OBC16

35.7

54.4

203

48.3

30.9

Others

292

ITT

163

462

362

ST/others

T60

134

129

T03

TTT

Lowest

51.5

64.3

34.0

47.5

18.5

Second

46J

603“

ITT

48.3“

227

Middle

383

To

22.9

48.2

282

Fourth

282

522’

16.4

482’

35.4

Highest

182

46T

“94

45.5

Lowest/highest

233

“139

“T62

1.04

ITT
th

Wealth groups

It is also important to add here that the proportion of women suffering from anaemia
is not low even within the richest quintile. This suggests that a substantially large
proportion of women in India, irrespective of the household wealth status, suffer from
iron deficiency anaemia. The huge disparity in women’s malnutrition between
economic and social groups in India is a matter of serious concern, as the levels ot
nutritional attainment appear to be not only unequal but also unjust.

Further analysis would suggest that though economic and social disparities matter
significantly and independently, the former seems to matter more, at least as tar as
women’s malnutrition is concerned, than the latter. Eastern states, mainly Bihar,
Jharkhand, Orissa and West Bengal, emerge as the repository of womens
malnutrition in India. Though these four states account for 22 per cent of women
considered for the analysis, 30 per cent of women suffering from CED and anaemia
together live in these states.
How does one change the situation? Ensuring equity in women’s rights to land,
property, capital assets, wages and livelihood opportunities would undoubtedly
impact positively on the issue, but underlying the deep inequity m woman s access to
nutrition is her own unquestioning acceptance of her status as an unequal member of
the family and society. Eventually, gender empowerment alone is likely to be the key
to the resolution of the hunger challenge amongst women in India (Ramachandran

2007)
16 Other backward castes

26
3.7

Child mortality

Malnutrition in children weakens their immune system, making them more
susceptible to disease and less able to fight off infection. It has been estimated that a
child is almost ten times more likely to die from key diseases if he or she is severely
underweight, and two and a half times more likely to die if he or she is moderately
underweight, as compared to an average weight child (Black et al., 2008). Given the
fact that more than 3.5 million children die globally on account of under-nutrition, it
emerges as a major factor leading to child deaths. Therefore, under-five mortality has
been taken by IFPRI as the third indicator for measuring the Hunger Index.
Figure 2: Neonatal, infant, child and under-five mortality rates (annual deaths
per 1000 live births)
120 -|

09.3
100 -

)4.9
l.5

80 -

74.3

67.6
60 -

- ---- ■ 57.0

48.6
43.4

40

33.4

39.0

29.3

18.4
20 -

0

NFHS 1

NFHS 2

Neo- natal mortality

—A— Child mortality

NFHS 3

—■— Infant mortality
—■— Under five mortality

About 2.1 million deaths occur annually among children aged 5 years or less in India.
Seven out of every 10 of these are due to diarrhoea, pneumonia, measles, or
malnutrition and often a combination of these conditions.
Child mortality is known to be the outcome of a wide variety of factors, such as the
nutritional status of the child and its mother, food availability in the family, the level
of immunization, availability of maternal and child health services, economic status,
availability of safe drinking water, basic sanitation, and so on. India accounts for 21
percent of a total of 9.7 million children dying globally before they reach the age of
five. This is despite the fact that child mortality has declined by 48 percent (from 142
to 74 annual deaths per 1000 live births) between 1990 and 2006. Under-five
mortality has strong correlation with the education level of mother; while it was 94.7
for illiterate mothers, it was only 29.7 for those who had 12 years of education. As
expected, child mortality is highest at 95.7 for ST social groups, followed by 88.1 for
SCs, and 59.2 for others (excluding OBCs for whom it was 72.8).

NFHS-3, reflects, to a large extent, the limited access to and reach of public health
services for women and children. In 2005-06, for instance, only 44 per cent of
children of 12-23 months were fully immunised. The national immunisation coverage
in urban areas has slipped over the past seven years from 61 per cent in 1998-99 to 58
per cent in 2005-06 and has increased only slightly in rural areas from 37 per cent to
39 per cent. Only 26 per cent of children with diarrhoea were given oral rehydration
solution (ORS) and barely two-thirds (64 per cent) of children suffering from acute
respiratory infection or fever were taken to a health facility. This shows both the poor
reach of public health services and also the limited accessibility of such services to

T1

children. There are huge gaps in women’s access to and the reach of maternal health
services. Improvements in women’s access to safe delivery, for instance, have been
minimal. Between 1998-99 and 2005-06, the proportion of births assisted by a doctor,
nurse, LHV, ANM or other health personnel went up marginally from 42 to 48 per
cent; and institutional births went up from 36 per cent to 41 per cent over the same
period.
A study conducted by Save the Children, which compares child mortality in a country
to its per capita income, shows that India lags far behind its poorer neighbours like
Bangladesh and Nepal, when it comes to reducing child deaths. A new Wealth and
Survival Index, which is part of the study, has ranked 41 countries on the criterion of
how well they use their resources to boost child survival rates. While Bangladesh and
Nepal are listed among the top ten performers, India stands at a low 16th in the index.
This can be elucidated by comparing India and Bangladesh. While India’s per capita
income increased by 42 percent from 2000 to 2006, its child mortality rate declined
from 94 to 76 per 1000 live births. As against that, over the same period, Bangladesh
saw a much smaller increase in per capita income — only 23 percent - but its child
mortality dropped from 92 to 69 (UNICEF 2007).
4

Food security

4.1 Consumption and prices
The NSSO data on consumer expenditure on food consumption indicates a declining
trend in the annual per capita consumption of cereals, for all classes of people, as
shown in Table 16.
Table 16: Trends in Cereal Consumption across Expenditure groups (kg per
month)
Percentile
RURAL

lowest 5
per cent

5 per cent10 per cent

40 per cent50 per cent

90 per cent95 per cent

95 per cent100 per cent

1993-94

9.68

11.29

13.33

14.98

15.78

1999-00

9.78

11.15

12.89

13.73

14.19

2004-05

9.88

10.87

12.16

12.77

13.50

Percentile

URBAN
lowest 5
per cent

5 per cent10 per cent

40 per cent50 per cent

90 per cent95 per cent

95 per cent100 per cent

1993-94

8.91

10.11

10.99

10.19

10.29

1999-00

8.99

10.15

10.80

9.94

9.72

2004-05

9.25

10.04

10.25

9.50

9.10

NSSO 2007, 61 st Round Report

The above Table clearly shows that as India moved to greater prosperity in the last
twenty years the cereal consumption of the rich went down, but there was no increase
for the poor. At any given point of time the cereal intake of the bottom 10 percent in
rural India continues to be at least 20 percent less than the cereal intake of the top

28
decile of the population, despite better access of the latter group to fruits, vegetables
and meat products. Their sedentary life style too should be taken into account while
assessing the difference between the two groups. For the upper segment of population
the decline may be attributed to a diversification in food consumption, easy access to
supply of other high value agricultural commodities, changed tastes and preferences,
and consumption of more expensive non-foodgrain products (Mittal, 2006). Higher
economic growth and per capita incomes thus contribute to reduction in per capita
demand for cereals for the rich.

However for those who are around the poverty line, this has to be understood as a
distress phenomenon, as with marginal increase in their incomes over time they are
forced to cut down on their food consumption to meet other pressing demands that
were not considered important in the past. For instance, as more schools open, the
poor too wish to send their children to schools, where expenses are incurred on
clothes, books, etc. despite the school fees being met by government. These expenses
would thus become a new item on the household budget, and food expenditure may
be curtailed to make room for it. Fighting sickness leads to another chunk of essential
expenses, for which opportunities did not exist in the past, as there were no doctors in
the vicinity. The share of fuel and light in total consumer expenditure has risen from under 6
per cent to 10 per cent in both rural and urban areas between 1972-73 and 2004-05. Finally,
the rural labouring masses have to spend on transport in order to earn their
livelihoods. Food is still needed, but not demanded.
A survey (Mander 2008) of 474 destitute people in eight villages found that intense
food shortages often demand the most unreasonable choices, such as between food
and medicines, between eating to save a life and relieving unbearable pain. Most
hungry people reported that their most hazardous tumble into pauperisation was
because they, or a loved one, fell gravely ill. Many old people simply try to wait out
an attack of illness, and if that does not work they consult a local untrained
practitioner, who demands his fees in advance, never guaranteeing cure. They do this
by cutting back their food intake even further.
Food prices - Between 1972-73 and 2004-05, the share of food in total consumer
expenditure has fallen from 73 per cent to 55 per cent in rural areas and from 64 per cent to 42
per cent in urban areas17. Could the falling share of food expenses in the total budget of
the poor be because of rising food prices? Not likely. In rural India, food (and
therefore calorie) prices moved along with general prices from 1983 until about 2000,
and then fell by a little less than five percent relative to general prices. In urban India,
there was a slow secular increase in the relative price of food, by less than five
percent, from 1983 until the late 1990s, followed by a more pronounced decline, by
more than ten percent, until the end of the period. In both sectors, the relative price of
food was lower in 2004-05 than at the start of the period in 1983. The decline in food
consumption cannot therefore be attributed to any increase in the relative price of
food. As it has been pointed out, the food budget of the poor has been squeezed out
because the cost of meeting the minimum non-food requirements has increased (Sen
2005). Thus, it is not possible for households around the poverty line to purchase their
initial food basket within their current food budget.

17 NSSO 61st round (Report No. 508)

29

Figure 3: Changes in price index (1993-94=100)

240
220

.

200
Primary articles
Food articles
All commodities

..

180
'



160

140

120
100

I

7


. ___

m co r*ep cp o>
■4- uo co
o>
o
a>

T-

co cn
o ct>
r^- ©o
o> o
o>
o
x- t-

o t— cm co
o o o o
co o
a> o
2 2
2
o
o o
t-

CM

CM CM

in CD
co r* co
c> o c> cp
m CO CD
co
o
o CD o
CD
o O CD CD
CM
Ol
CM

CM

CM

Howcycr, as figure 4 shows, there has been faster increase in food prices after 200506 This has resulted in higher spending on cereals, but the quantity of cereals
consumed has not increased. Between 2005-06 and 2006-07 the average per capita
monthly rural consumption of cereals fell from 11.92 to 11.69 kg, but the price
increased from 106 to 115 Rupees. For urban areas the figure was from 9.76 to 9.63
kg, and the increase in money spent was from 110 to 119 Rupees (Economic Times
11^ November, 2008, based on NSSO 63rd round).
4.2

Food production, procurement and availability at the macro-level

At the macro level foodgrain availability in India is calculated as 87.5 per cent of
gross production (the rest is estimated as requirement for seeds, farm animal feed, and
waste) plus net imports minus changes in government stocks. Assuming no net
change in private stocks this can be taken as a good proxy for overall foodgrain
consumption in the country.
During the last fifty years before Independence foodgrain availability declined from
545 grams to 407 grams per head per day. Considering five-year averages India saw a
rise in the foodgrain availability per head from 416 grams during 1950-55 to 485
grams by 1989-91 (Patnaik 2004). However since then there has been the slide to a
low of 445 gram per head per day by 2006, a level not seen since the drought years of
1970s.

30

Figure 4: Per capita foodgrain
availability per day in gms

500
480
460
440
420
400

CM

co

<0

co

o
o>

O|

a
o

CM

(based on Economic Survey, GOI, 2007-08)
The fall in availability is because of both a drop in production and increasing exports.
From 2001 to 2005 the government exported a record 28 million tonnes of foodgrains
at subsidised rates. Independent India has never before seen such huge exports, and it
was highly unethical that the government preferred to feed foreigners and their cattle
by exporting foodgrains, applying a heavy subsidy to beat the low world price, rather
than undertake widespread internal distribution of foodgrains.

Figure 5: Annual per capita production of foodgrains
(average of five years)

205
200

195
190

185

i

180
1990-95

1995-00

2001/04

2005/08

(based on Economic Survey, GOI, 2007-08)

31

Despite the fact that the growth of foodgrain production in the period 1989-2004 was
lower than the increase in population during the same period, the procurement of
cereals on government account went up, suggesting a decline in poor people s
consumption and their purchasing power. This may have happened because of the
structural imbalances like a high Minimum Support Price (MSP), rising capital
intensity, lack of land reforms, failure of poverty alleviation programmes, and no new
technological breakthrough in agriculture. It could also be due to production problems
in less endowed regions like erratic rainfall, soil erosion and water run-off, lack of
access to credit and markets, and poor communications which led to a dangerous
situation of huge surplus in PCI godowns during 2000-03 coupled with widespread
hunger.

Figure 6: Average annual imports in Million Tonnes

IS

8

6
fl

4

I

2
0

li

1962- 1967- 1972- 1977- 1982- 1987- 1992- 199t- 2|0<
I 56 19576r 66
71
76
81
86
91
96 W
0

'
■2

■4

i

-6

■8i
(based on Economic Survey, GOI, 2007-08)
The falling availability and increase in government procurement reflects a contraction
of effective demand18, as the poor are forced to spend a greater part of their incomes
on transport, health, and education. In other words, non-food items have become more
“essential” than food in a particular sense. This argument is supported by empirical
evidence from various sample surveys, as between 1972-73 and 2004-05 the
proportion of food in total consumer expenditure has fallen from 73 per cent to 55 per
cent in rural areas and from 64 per cent to 42 per cent in urban areas (Ramachandran
2008).

18 This is despite the fact that the expenditure of bottom three deciles increased by about 10 per cent
during 1993-2005.

> '‘'■5

32

Figure 7: Stocks of foodgrains in government
godowns in July in million tonnes

65
55

45
35

25
15
CO
O)
CD

a>

o
o
o

CM

o
o

CM

CM

o
o

CM

CO
O
<=>
CM

o
o
CM

m

CD
CD
CM

CO
CD
CD
CM

O
CD
CM

CO
CD
CD
CM

(based on Economic Survey, GOI, 2007-08)
Because of a lack of growth in agriculture after the mid-1990s there has beenL an
employment decline, income decline and hence a fall in aggregate demand by the
rural poor. Normally when there is a fall in per capita output and government stocks
are depleted, net imports take place in order to maintain availability per head at an
unchanged level; but precisely the opposite happened m India during 1999-2004.
Despite falling per capita output, there were both rising net exports as well as huge
addition to stocks year after year. This was a highly abnormal situation never seen
before in independent India: it reflects the unprecedented magnitude of continuous
demand-deflation of foodgrains, especially in the rural sector since 1996 (Sen 2004).
19

4.2.1 Recent developments and imports
When the GOI decided to open up wheat procurement for large companies in 2006 the
official procurement fell from a high annual level of 15-19 million tonnes in 2002-05
to 9 million tonnes only in 2006. It had to resort to massive imports of 5.4 million
tonnes in 2006 followed by 1.8 million tonnes in 2007 at a price higher than what it
paid to its farmers. After these difficulties government became careful and banned
export of wheat as early as February 2007, and the export of non-basmati vaneties of
rice in October 2007 to prevent domestic shortage due to export. The bumper
foodgrain harvest in 2007-08 and various direct and indirect restrictions on large-scale
purchases by the private sector in 2008 helped GOI procure an impressive 23 MT of
wheat which also helped in controlling its market price. However, the biggest factor
that prevented a sharp rise in food prices in India was that fertilizer pnces and diesel
prices were not increased in response to the increase in international pnces. It is worth
mentioning that about half of the increase in global food prices is due to the increase
19 Based on Chand 2007, 2008

33
in prices of crude oil. By providing a subsidy on fertilizer and diesel, India could
ensure that the increase in global crude oil prices, which raised global food prices by
47 per cent, does not affect food prices in India.

4.3 Global developm en ts
The per capita annual production of cereals in the world increased from 271 kg during
1961-65 to 295 kg during 1966-70, which were the initial years of the green
revolution. The uptrend continued for about two decades and per capita cereal
production peaked by the mid-1980s at a level of 334 kg per person per year. The
growth rate of cereal production decelerated to 1.09 per cent after the mid-1980s,
compared to 2.51 per cent in 1961-85. The recent growth rate turned out to be lower
than the growth rate in the population even though the growth rate in the population
was decreasing. The per capita production of cereals declined to less than 315 kg in
the first eight years of the 21st century (Chand 2008).

Though there has been some improvement in per capita availability of cereals during
the last four years (2003-07) this increase has not been available for use as food and
feed, due to diversion of foodgrain for the production of biofuel. When total
production is netted out for the com used for biofuel in the United States then the per
capita production falls to 307 kg, the lowest in any five-year period after 1966-70.
This shows that the shortage of staple food has been building up over several years
and it became quite large in the recent years.
The per capita consumption of cereals, meat, milk and eggs in India, China, US and
the World averages are presented in Table 17.
Table 17: Per Capita Consumption during 2004-06 (kg/year)

India

China
China

All cereals

TTST

287.9
2875

953"

316

Meat

~~53

56.8~
5fr8

126.6

402

Milk

84.5

22.7
22/7

Na

9O

21.6
F8
2T6
Eggs
-------------------------------------

152

“95

US

World

Chand 2008

It is pertinent to mention that consumption here indicates total use as food and feed
which thus captures the impact of dietary change on cereal demand as feed. The per
capita consumption of cereals in the US is 953 kg, which is three times the World
average, 3.3 times the average in China and 5.4 times the average m India. The mam
factor behind such a high level of cereal consumption in the US is their meat and egg
consumption. An average US consumer consumes 127 kg of meat in a year, which is
more than the quantity of meat consumed by 25 consumers in India.
4.3.1 Recent global financial crisis
The recent global meltdown in the financial and equity markets follows hard on the
heels of soaring food price and energy crisis caused primarily on account of
intensified bio-fuel programme. Global commodity prices, though still high, have
dipped due to a good harvest in the current season. According to the latest issue of
FAO's Crop Prospects and Food Situation report, global grain production this year is
forecast to increase 4.9 per cent to a record 2,232 million tonnes. Commodity prices
have dipped in recent times as investors anticipate a recession. Wheat futures for

34
December delivery closed recently at 62 per cent down from a record set in February.
Com futures dipped 53 per cent from their all-time high and soybean futures
registered 47 per cent lower .
Commodity prices are currently declining, mainly on the expectation of favourable
crop prospects but also due to the threat of a global recession. It is feared that
borrowing, bank lending, official development aid, foreign direct investment and
workers’ remittances may be compromised by a deepening financial crisis. The impact
of the financial crisis may also be felt in developing countries at the macro level with
potentially negative impact on agriculture and food security. The falling grain prices
and liquidity problems may cause lower investment in agriculture and shrinkage in
crop area and reduced harvest in the major exporting countries. Given the low grain
stock, this situation can lead to another turn of record high food prices next year. The
subprime meltdown, downturn in the equity market, intensification of bio-fuel
programme leading to use of food for fuel and consequent rise in food prices,
speculation in commodity futures, fluctuations in currency exchange rates, the threat
of recession, increasing corporate monopoly over the farm sector and wilful distortion
in global farm trade have collectively endangered food security.

However global financial crisis should not be used as an excuse for inaction in the
worsening battle against wrenching hunger across the developing world. The world
now has the responsibility of fulfilling the Millennium Developmental Goals (MDGs)
by lifting nearly one billion people out of poverty, who do not have enough food to
eat on a day-to-day basis. This is the time to think of an alternative model of
development as the belief in the self-regulating market was no longer credible.
Implications for India: India has almost insulated itself against transmission of the
current level of an abnormally high global prices of cereals. Wheat prices in India
increased by about 20 per cent between December 2005 and 2006, which is
considered quite high. International prices in the same period increased by 24 per
cent. Remarkably is that between December 2006 and December 2007 international
wheat prices increased by 80 per cent, whereas domestic prices declined by 1.3 per
cent. The annual rate of inflation estimated on a month-to-month basis shows that
food price inflation in international markets21 in the first half of this year has crossed
40 per cent, whereas in India it has remained below 8 per cent. This was due to



an increase in food production during 2006-07 and 2007-08 in which
favourable weather also played an important role,



timely and effective government intervention in the domestic market, and

.

almost complete insulation of the cost of crop production from transmission of
the increase in crude oil prices in the international market.

4.4 Future scenario for India ’sfoodproduction
While in the short and medium term, there might be surplus of cereals in the country,
primarily due to lack of purchasing power, these prospects are likely to diminish in
the years to come (Mittal 2008; Chand 2007a).

2° Based on http://www.financialexpress.com/news/global-meltdown-to- have-a-negative-impact-on3
food-security/379640/0
21 There are indications of sharp fall in the international food prices in the last three months.

$

35
Demand projections in general are estimated on the basis of assumptions about the
base year demand, population, expenditure elasticity and economic growth. Assuming
that GDP grows by 8 per cent for the next twenty years, the total cereal demand
projected for 2011 and 2026 is 188 million tonnes (mt) and 274 mt respectively. The
supply of cereals is estimated to be 210 mt in 2011, 242 mt in 2021 and 260 mt in
2026. Thus India may be running a surplus in the short run, but is likely to fall short
of the demand in the long run. This situation is even more alarming for edible oil,
sugarcane and pulses. To meet the future food requirements, the country shall have to
either increase agricultural production, or depend on imports. If India wishes to avoid
large scale imports the policy focus needs to be laid, towards productivity
enhancement in agriculture, through public investment in irrigation, development of
roads, power, and technology.
Unfortunately the trend so far has been disappointing. After recording unprecedented
growth of 4.7 per cent a year during the period of Eighth Five Year Plan (1992-1997),
growth of the agriculture and allied sectors decelerated to 2.1 per cent during the
Ninth Five Year Plan (1997-2002). It further dipped to 1.0 per cent during the Tenth
Five year Plan (2002-07) against the targeted growth of 4 per cent per annum.
India’s low average wheat and rice yields compared with other major world producers
suggest that there is significant scope for further boosting yields and output. Rice
yields are among the lowest for major producers and wheat yields remain near the
world (and U.S.) average despite the fact that a relatively high share—about 87
percent—of Indian wheat area is irrigated. Although roughly 90 percent of wheat area
and 75 percent of rice area is already planted to HYVs, average wheat yields in major
States remain about 25 percent lower than levels achieved in expenment stations,
while rice yields are about 50 percent lower (Jha et al 2007). Increasing the yields
would however need new policies, discussed in section 5.1.1.

36

5

Analysis of major programmes and policy options

In the foregoing sections we have discussed some of the causes of hunger and its
implications for healthy development of body and mind. There are of course larger
policy issues that aggravate the hunger situation in India. These and the ones already
discussed are summarised below.

Underlying causes of hunger in India



Falling per capita crop, especially food production in the last ten years.



Increasing share of surplus states and large farmers in food production,
resulting in artificial surplus that is exported, thus further reducing availability
of foodgrains.



Increasing inequality, with only marginal increase in the per capita
expenditure of the bottom 30%. From their meagre income the poor are forced
to spend more on medical care, education, transport, fuel, and light, thus
reducing the share of their expenditure on food.

Poor access of the bottom half of the population to expensive foods, such as
pulses, vegetables, oil, fruits, and meat products which provide essential
proteins, fats, and micro-nutrients. This leads to under-development of human
body and mind, affecting the ability of individuals to work productively, think
clearly, and resist disease.
• Low status of women in Indian society, their early marriage, low weight at
pregnancy and illiteracy leading to low weight of new bom babies.









Poor childcare practices, such as not immediately starting breastfeeding after
birth no exclusively breastfeeding for the first five months, irregular and
insufficient complementary feeding afterwards, and lack of quick disposal of
child’s excreta.
Poor supply of government services, such as immunisation, access to medical
care, and lack of priority to primary health care in government programmes.
These factors combined with poor food availability in the family, unsafe
drinking water and lack of sanitation lead to high child under-nutrition and
permanent damage to their physical and mental capabilities.

Major food related programmes, such as PDS and ICDS are plagued by
corruption, leakages, errors in selection, procedural delays, poor allocations
and little accountability. They also tend to discriminate against and exclude
those who most need them, by social barriers of gender, age, caste, and
disability; and State hostility to urban poor migrants, street and slum residents,
dispersed hamlets, and unorganised workers, such as hawkers.

The policy options, especially relating to the existing programmes are discussed in
this section now.

37
5.7

Agricultural production

The agricultural scene in India in the last fifteen years has four features that
distinguish it from the earlier ‘green revolution’ phase (1970-85). First, the policy
approach to agriculture in the 1990s has been to secure an increase in production
through subsidies on inputs such as power, water, and fertilizer, and by increasing the
minimum support price (MSP) rather than through building new capital assets in
irrigation, power and rural infrastructure. According to the Planning Commission,
budgetary subsidies in agriculture increased from around 3 percent of agricultural
GDP around the late-1970s to about 7 percent in the early 2000s. During the same
period, public investment in agriculture declined from 3.4 percent of agricultural GDP
to 1.9 percent (Bisaliah 2007).
This has shifted the production base from low-cost regions to high-cost ones, causing
an increase in the cost of production, regional imbalance, and an increase in the
burden of storage and transport of foodgrains. The equity, efficiency, and
sustainability of the current approach are questionable. The subsidies do not improve
income distribution or the demand for labour (Saxena 2004). The boost in output from
the subsidy-stimulated use of fertilizer, pesticides and water has the potential to
damage aquifers and soils - an environmentally unsustainable approach that may
partly explain the rising costs and slowing growth and productivity in agriculture,
notably in Punjab and Haryana. Although private investment in agriculture has grown,
this has often involved macroeconomic inefficiencies (such as private investment in
diesel generating sets instead of public investment in electricity supply). Public
investment in agriculture has fallen dramatically since the 1980s and so has the share
of agriculture in the total gross capital formation (GCF). Instead of promoting lowcost options that have a higher capital-output ratio, present policies have resulted in
excessive use of capital on farms, such as too many tubewells in water-scarce regions.
Second, the intensity of private capital is in fact increasing for all class of farmers but
at a faster pace in the ‘Green Revolution’ areas and for larger farmers Thus,
fertilizers pesticides and diesel accounted for a mere 14.9 per cent of the total inputs
in 1970-1 but 55.1 per cent in 1994-5. For large farmers in commercialised regions
the contribution of purchased inputs may have now become as high as 80 per cent.
But the proportion of output sold has increased at a much slower rate than the
proportion of monetized inputs, including hired labour. The implication of this is a
resource squeeze in agriculture. Whereas the need for resources to purchase these
inputs has been increasing, the marketable surplus has been increasing at a slower rate
to contribute to this, as the growth of non-farm employment has become very
sluggish. It is not surprising that the repayment of loans is such a problem m Indian
agriculture and has even led to suicides in some cases. A better strategy would be to
concentrate on small and marginal farmers, and on eastern and ramfed areas where
returns to both capital and labour are high. The need is also for better factor
productivity in agriculture and for new technologies, which would be more labour
intensive and would cut cash costs.
Whereas the use of capital has increased amongst the small and marginal farmers,
markets in eastern and central India continue to be imperfect. Therefore the poor
farmers are forced to sell part of their product to pay their loans (mostly from
informal sources) for purchased seeds, water and fertilizer, but they do not get a good
price and market conditions benefit the trader and moneylender more than they
benefit the producer.

38
Third, the proportion of total bank credit earmarked for agriculture has fallen from
nearly 18 per cent in the mid-1980s to 10.0 per cent in 2005-2006. This decline has
been much sharper in direct lending. A substantial part of agricultural loans since the
1990s has been in the form of indirect credit, that is, lending for various intermediary
agencies and instruments like the Rural Electrification Corporation (REC), the special
bonds issued by NABARD (National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development)
and deposits placed by banks in Rural Infrastructure Development Fund (RIDE) in
lieu of priority sector lending. In the same period there has been a precipitate fall in
small borrower accounts (credit limits of Rs 25,000 or below) from Rs 62.55 million
to Rs 36.87 million or more pointedly, in terms of amount outstanding from 25 per
cent to 5.4 per cent. Small loans are mostly agricultural loans.
Undoubtedly, institutional credit has been scarce for the agricultural sector rather
significantly in the 1990s and in this decade. Are banks reluctant to offer agricultural
loans because their earning potential from these loans has been relatively low? A
more palpable cause for the banks’ poor lending to agriculture or to small borrowers
is their professional reluctance to operate in rural areas. And this is a more daunting
issue to be addressed. Given the option, the scheduled commercial banks will not
operate in rural areas. Since March 1995 after the disbanding of branch licensing
policy and the granting of freedom to bank boards, the number of rural branches has
declined from 32 981 to 32,137, this means the closure of roughly 840 rural branches
instead of an addition of at least 8,000 branches under normal circumstances . This
approach to rural banking has spawned a serious institutional vacuum in rural credit.
It is no use goading banks to expand their rural and agricultural credit base without
ensuring that there is an adequate spread of the institutional network for rural lending.
And lastly, groundwater as opposed to surface and sub-soil (through shallow wells)
water has become the main source of irrigation. Due to this nearly 30 percent of the
blocks in the country are presently classified as semi-critical, critical or overexploi e
(mostly in ‘green revolution’ areas) as groundwater use exceeds the rate o
groundwater recharge. As there is no effective control over digging of tubewells in
water-scarce regions, farmers are borrowing money from informal sources at high
interest rates to dig tubewells, but many such borings fail leading to indebtedness, and
even suicides. Since sinking a bore well involves a heavy investment upfront, only the
rich or the affluent farmer goes in for it, whereas the small farmer continues to depend
on the shallow dug well that has been in existence for decades. Bore wells dram much
larger quantities of water and it is usually from the same aquifers that feed die dug
wells So in a village the small farmer is adversely affected, when the richer farmers
install bore wells fitted with electric motors. The affluent farmers owning bore wells
and electric motors comer most of the benefit of electricity subsidy too. Ironically,
they in turn sell their surplus water to the adjacent small farmers at commercial rates.
The built-in biases of the green revolution strategy now stand exposed.
The impact of these four factors has been increasing landlessness, sharpened
inequalities (both inter-state and inter-class), and stagnation in production. The mdex
number of agricultural production rose by 4.4 per cent annually during the 1980 s, but
dropped to 2.8 per cent from 1990-91 to 1996-97, and the growth rate further
plummeted to just 0.5 per cent in the next ten years. The trend for foodgrams is
similar. During the eleven year period 1996 to 2007, foodgrain production increased
22 www.solidnet.org/cgibin/agent?parties/0370=india,_communist_party_of_india/917india28jun04.doc

39
only by 9 per cent, from 199 to 217 mt, or much less than one per cent a year as
against an annual rate of growth of 3.5 percent achieved during the 1980s. The
availability of cereals declined from a peak of 468 grams per capita per day in 199091 to 412 grams per capita per day in 2005-06, indicating a decline of 13 per cent
during this period. The availability of pulses declined from 42 grams per capita per
day (72 grams in 1956- 57) to 33 grams per capita per day during the same period.
Moreover, poverty reduction has become disconnected from agricultural growth
because as opposed to substantial agricultural growth in the 1980s, there was little
growth between 1997 and 2006. This has also resulted in a slower increase of real
agricultural wages, with the poorer states showing no increase or even a decline in
wages. In addition, the casualisation of a mass of rural workers without safety nets,
the feminization of agricultural labour accompanied by low wages, and the
persistence of child labour are worrying trends.
The stagnation is despite the soaring annual cost of food subsidies, which rose from
Rs 61 billion in 1996-97 to Rs 120 billion in 2000-01 to Rs 310 billion in 2007-08. If
subsidies on free rural power and fertilizers are added the figure may well reach a
staggering figure of Rs 1000 billion, or about Rs 70 per day per poor rural family.

5.1.1 What needs to be done?
It is thus obvious that Indian agriculture is in a serious crisis, and needs several
innovative policy interventions, some are discussed below.
The most important intervention that is needed is more investment in irrigation,
power, and roads in poorer regions. It is essential to realize the potential for
production surpluses in Central and Eastern India, where most poor live. Many states
in this region do not benefit from the MSP for rice, as FCI does not buy paddy from
the farmers in these states, but buys rice from the millers . A basic focus of policy
should therefore, be to ensure effective price support in states and areas with future
production potential. To achieve the growth target of 4.5 per cent in agriculture, the
investment should grow at an annual rate of about 12 per cent, as compared to the
present level of about 5 per cent.
Since the level of public investment is an important determinant of private investment
through complementary/inducement effect, the choice of public sector investment
portfolio is crucial. Public investment has to be considered as a policy instrument for
reducing regional agricultural development disparities and for realizing the full
potential of small and marginal farmers. Any demand-induced diversification would
place new demands on market infrastructure (like more investment on cold storage,
rural roads, communication, and the marketing network) and institutions. In fact, price
induced crop diversification is not sustainable in the absence of back up from non­
price factors such as technology, irrigation and rural infrastructure.
Water is a critical input for achieving higher agricultural growth and ensuring greater
food security. Only about 40 percent of the cultivated area in India is currently
irrigated. Greater emphasis should be placed on shifting the balance in favour of
surface irrigation and on the more effective use of existing irrigation systems.

23 FCI buys paddy from fanners only in Punjab, Haryana and Andhra Pradesh. In the last few years,
some states, such as Chhattisgarh and UP have started buying paddy directly from the farmers,
providing to them the much needed price support.

40

Many states, however, lack the policy, regulatory, and institutional framework for
efficient, sustainable, and equitable allocation and use of water, or for articulating the
environmental costs of inefficient use. Many states often do not allocate sufficient
public funds for the operation and maintenance of canals. This leads to the rapid
deterioration of irrigation canals and reduces the availability of water to farmers.
Limited cost recovery also limits funds for operations and maintenance and undercuts
farmer incentives to use water more efficiently, leading to waterlogging and salinity
problems in some areas. Some states have adopted participatory irrigation
management on a wide scale to improve the management and sustainability of surface
irrigation systems. These need to be replicated on a large scale.
Free power to farmers by some states or highly subsidized power encourages the
excessive use of ground water. This has led to an increase in the overexploited areas
in the country and large fiscal costs to state governments. This must be checked.
The bans or restrictions on land leasing limit the access to land by poor and landless
rural households and they drive tenancy underground. They also limit the productivity
of land use. However, reverse tenancy from the poor to the rich should not be
legalised.
Regulated markets were supposed to improve efficiency, but many official market
committees such as in UP, Punjab, and Haryana make it illegal for farmers to sell
through alternative channels, like selling directly to millers. The markets have thus
emerged as taxing mechanisms, rather than facilitating farmers to get the best price.
This needs to be changed and farmers should be allowed to develop direct contact
with large (and even corporate) buyers, with a complete ban on exports.
The present extraction rates for both wheat and rice are about 10 to 30 percent below
the international standards due to reservation of agro-processmg units for the small
sector which uses inefficient technologies. Therefore, licensing controls on the Flour
Mills and other food processing industry should be removed. De-reserve food
processing units, especially rapeseed and groundnut processing units, from the SSI
list. On the whole, laws and controls have repressed private foodgram marketing,
undercutting its potential contribution to long-term food security.
Finally, pay more attention to rainfed areas, especially eastern plains, where land is
fertile and groundwater is still unexploited. These regions need better infrastructure o
markets, roads and power.
Agriculture and the poverty link: How is poverty reduction correlated with
agricultural production? Early pessimism with the Green Revolution (Gnffin 1974)
was soon replaced by an agrarian optimism that connected poverty reduction with
agricultural growth. Ahluwalia (1978) observed an inverse relationship between
poverty and agricultural performance for rural India as a whole. According to Lipton
(1989) this was because the new modem varieties of grain became smallholder­
friendly: they yielded more even with low inputs, were more pest-proof, and, unlike
hybrids, did not need the annual replenishment of seeds. They also raised labour use
per acre-year, thus benefiting the poor. Therefore one needs to stress the fundamental
role of the agricultural sector in supporting rural livelihoods, generating employment
and providing food security.
However there could be situations where agriculture could harml some people
(Bardhan 1985), and therefore one must 1take precautions against the following
developments:

41



adoption of labour-displacing machinery



eviction of small tenants by large landlords



driving some small farmers, with limited access to resources and credit, out of
cultivation and into crowding the agricultural labour market



a similar crowding of the agricultural labour market by displaced village
artisans, as the demand of the new rural rich shifts away from local handicrafts
and services to mass-produced urban consumer goods and services



the use of pump sets, enabling richer farmers to appropriate communal
groundwater, resulting in a possible drop in water tables and making the
traditional shallow well technology even less effective than before for poorer
farmers without pump sets



the increased political bargaining power of the rural rich and surplus regions,
resulting in higher administered prices of foodgrains (of which the rural poor
are net buyers), while typically wages lag behind the price rises (and as
monetization of wage payments increases with agricultural progress).

5.2 Agricultural labour and wage employment programmes
Household food security is contingent on many factors - the ability to grow enough
for self-sufficiency among farming households, and/or having enough income to buy
food. Access to food then depends on prices at which food can be bought or prices at
which the cost of cultivation is covered to yield a decent return for others. The
problems of small farmers have already been discussed above, here we touch upon the
plight of the agricultural labourers.
With falling agricultural growth rates and increasing capital intensity, the growth rate
of employment has lagged (Lanjouw and Mugai 2008). Unemployment among
agricultural labour households has sharply increased from 9.5 per cent in 1993-94 o
15 3 per cent in 2004-05. There is a secular decline in employment elasticity in
agriculture over time (Bhalla and Hazell 2003). What is of special significance is the
predominance of women among rural workers and their larger numbers as subsidiary
and casual workers.
As per the NSS data, the proportion of households withoutjmyr access to land in the
total rural households has increased from 25.1 per cent in 1973-74 to 38.7 per cent in
1993-94 to 40.9 per cent in 1999-00 and further to 43.1 per cent during 20 - . ue
to the increase in supply, the rate of growth of real wages of adult casual labourers has
seen a declining trend, as shown in Figure 8.
At the same time, casual labour and self-employment in the non-farm sector reveals
greater involvement by disadvantaged groups in 2004 than in the preceding rounds.
The poor are thus pushed into low-return casual non-farm activities due to lack of
opportunities in the agricultural sector rather than being pulled by high returns offered
bv the non-farm sector. This has resulted in a decline in the wages of adult casual
labourers in the urban sector during 1999-2000 to 2004-05 by 0.51 per cent annually
for men and by 0.74 per cent for women (Sundaram 2007).

42

Figure 8: Average daily earnings of workers in
agricultural operations (Rs) at 1986-87 prices
16

14 4
12 1
10

-♦-Men
Women

8 I

6 I

21

4II

oh
1983

1987-88

1993-94

1999-2000

2004-05

(Jha 2007)
As it may take time for agriculture to create more jobs at higher wages for the poor,
government needs to step in with wage employment programmes in districts where
wages are depressed. However, allocations under wage employment schemes have
been grossly inadequate. The legal guarantee of 100 days wages under the National
Rural Employment Guarantee Act (NREGA), according to GAG, has been fulfilled in
only 3 per cent of the cases. West Bengal’s poor implementation of this project left at
least Rs 6.50 billion unspent (Anandabazar Patrika, February 3, 2008; Statesman,
February 11 2008). A great number of people are not given job cards, those who have
jobs are given (on an average) 12-14 days work. In backward villages, a government
survey shows that only 38 per cent of people got work under the NREGA.

According to a recent press note by the Ministry of Programme Implementation and
Statistics on ‘Employment and Unemployment Situation in India: 2005-06 , among
people aged 15 years and above in the rural area, only 5 per cent got public works,
per cent sought but did not get public works. In addition to increased outlays the
scheme should have a food component, now that the GOI has a comfortable stock of

foodgrains.
The National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (NREGA), which in principle gives
every person who is willing to work the statutory right to 100 days of guaranteed
wage labour at minimum wages per family, is legally open to all destitute pe°Plein practice, a study (Mander 2008) found that it remains barred to most. Old people
report that they are discouraged from applying for work, with remarks such as that
“you are too old and will fall sick because of the heavy work involved”. Instead of
identifying less physically demanding work like standing guard at the sites, taking
care of children, filling stones and soil in baskets, and planting and irrigating saplings,
they are given the most back-breaking work, and are therefore themselves eventually
compelled to opt out of the work. Many older widows are turned away openly: ‘When
I go to ask for work, they say that this is your age to relax, but if I do not work, how

43
will I live?’ Others are again intentionally given work that they cannot manage, so
they leave ‘voluntarily’. We suggest as follows:
1. Ensure that single women, aged and disabled people in practice enjoy at least
equal legal claim to employment in NREGA works as households ‘led’ by
able-bodied men, and that their work guarantee should be extended through an
amendment in the Act to 150 days.

2. NREGA guidelines and handbooks in each state should carefully identify
specific tasks in public works which can be undertaken by disabled adults and
aged people; and they should be encouraged to undertake such tasks when
people of these categories apply for work.
3. Provide separate NREGA job cards for all ‘single’ women, regardless of
whether they live alone, with dependents, or in their natal or husband s home.
Likewise for aged, infirm and disabled people who may or may not live with
‘able-bodied’ caregivers.

As already discussed, there has been no real increase in per capita food expenditure
for the poor, particularly after 1987-88. In fact, the food share has fallen at all levels
of per-capita expenditure, including the poverty line. Both Dharm Narain (1979) and
Saith (1981) have found a very strong positive association between rural poverty and
the consumer price index for agricultural laborers, therefore the poor must get not
only more employment opportunities at higher wages but also cheap subsidized
foodgrains24, as discussed below.

5.3 Public Distribution System (PDS)
With a network of more than 0.4 million Fair Price Shops (FPS) claiming to annually
distribute commodities worth more than Rs 150 billion to about 160 million families,
the PDS in India is perhaps the largest distribution network of its type in the world.
These shops distribute a total of 35 kg of wheat and rice to about 65 million BPL
families at Rs 4.2 per kg for wheat and Rs 5.6 for rice (present market rate is about
double the PDS price). Another 25 million poorest families (referred to as AAY
families) get 35 kg of foodgrains at a highly subsidized rate of Rs 2 per kg. for wheat
and Rs 3 per kg for rice. In addition there are welfare schemes such as hot cooked
mid-day meals (MDM) for school going children, and supplementary nutrition (SNP)
for pre-school children.
The overall distribution under PDS and welfare schemes has shown considerable
improvement in the last five years, at least on paper. The offtake of BPL/AAY
foodgrains as the percentage of allocation has gradually improved since 2001-02 from
59 per cent to 78 per cent in 2007-08.

24 Some marginal and small farmers may also be ‘net purchasers’ of cereals because either they do not
produce enough to meet their needs, or they are forced to sell cereals soon after harvesting to meet
other expenditures and buy back cereals for own consumption during lean season.

44
Table 19: Production, Procurement & Offtake of Foodgrains (in mT)

1997
-98

2001
-02

2002
-03

2003
-04

2004
-05

2005
-06

2006
-07

2007
-08

Food Subsidy in
billion Rupees

79

176

240

270

290

235

242

313

Production of
foodgrains

192.3

212.9

174.8

213.2

198.4

208.6

217.3

230.7

Procurement of
foodgrains

23.6

42.6

40.3

34.5

41.4

42.2

34.3

37.4

Distribution
through FPS

17.0

13.8

20.1

24.2

29.7

31.4

31.6

33.5

Disposal though
welfare schemes

2.1

8.9

11.4

13.5

10.6

9.7

5.1

3.9

Open market sale

0.06

5.6

5.66

9.66

0.25

1.1

.0

.02

Subsidized exports

0

4.7

12.5

10.3

1.0

(based on several issues of Monthly Food bulletin, Ministry of Food & Consumer
Protection)
However, not all states lift their entire quota, Bihar and Orissa being the worst
defaulters, lifting less than half their allotment. In 2006-07, they lifted only 22 per
cent and 58 per cent of the allotted food grains for the BPL category. It is significant
that the allocation of the poorer states such as UP, Bihar and Assam have more than
doubled since 1997, yet due to poor off-take by the states and even poorer delivery by
the FPS to BPL families, the scheme has not made any impact on the nutrition levels
in these states.
There are significant inclusion and exclusion errors in possession of BPL ration cards,
as shown below:
Table 20: Possession of ration cards by type, and socio-economic status, 2004/05
Per cent of HH
Per cent of HH
Per cent of HH
Per cent of HH
that possess
that possess BPL that possess APL
that possess
AAY card
card
card
ration card
4.9
28.2
44.2
77.3
Poorest
2.7
38.4
40.5
81.6
Q2
1.8
41.6
Q3“~
40.0
83.3
Q4 “

84.9

30.5

52.7

1.7

Richest

87.5

16.8

70.1

0.6

Rural

84.8

38.7

43.2

2.9

Urban

78.8

20.8

57.0

1.0

45
Source: World Bank 2007
Table 20 clearly shows that almost half of the poor are left out from the appropriate
category of ration cards.
All is not well with the Public Distribution System in India. The Planning
Commission (2008) has concluded that 4PDS seems to have failed in serving the objective
of making foodgrains available to the poor. If it had, the consumption levels of cereals should
not have fallen on average—as it has consistently over the last two decades.
The problems associated with the PDS are summarized below.
1. Large errors of exclusion of BPL families and inclusion of above poverty line
(APL) families

2. Prevalence of ghost BPL/AAY cards in the custody of FPS dealer
3. Diversion of subsidised grains to unintended beneficiaries
4. Section of the APL households not lifting their ration quota and thus a part of
the entitlement of these households leaking out of the PDS supply chain.

5. The present procedure for selection of BPL beneficiaries is opaque,
bureaucratic, and does not involve gram sabhas (council of all voters in the
village). The basis on which village wise cap on the maximum number of
entitled beneficiaries is fixed, is not clear and not well defined.
6

Some states, such as Bihar, Jharkhand and UP are not being given the APL
quota on the ground that they did not take it in the past when the market price
was low. This policy favours the southern states which have been subsidising
the APL quota out of state funds, and punishes the poorer states.

7. The selection procedure of FPS dealers is not transparent, and often based on
patronage or bribes.

8. Inadequate storage capacity with FCI in some districts.

9. The poor financial condition of many State Food Corporations who are
supposed to transport grain from the FCI depot to the FPS.
10. Allocations from the GOI are valid only for a month, and if the state
government is not able to lift within that time, its quota lapses.
11. The poor do not have cash to buy 35 kg at a time, and often they are not
permitted to buy in instalments.
12. The low quality of foodgrains
13. Weak monitoring, lack of transparency and inadequate accountability of
officials implementing the scheme.
14. The price charged exceeds the official price.
15. The shop does not open for more than 2-3 days in a month, and the card
* holders are not allowed to lift their quota of previous months, or to lift their
quota in instalments during a month.

16. Ration cards are mortgaged to ration shop owners.
17. There is no grievance redressal mechanism.



46
18. A large number of homeless and poor living in unauthorised colonies in urban
areas have been denied ration cards, and are thus unable to avail the PDS,
despite being Indian citizens.
19. Seasonal and temporary migrants face problems in receiving their entitlements
during the period they are out from the village.

5.3.1

Policy and procedural reforms

The following policy and procedural reforms may help in improving both the offtake
of PDS rations and availability for the poor:

Improving procedure for selection of BPL: This must be changed in favour of a
more transparent and participative procedure. The number of BPL cards should be
fixed for each district, based on the percentage of SC, ST population and the inverse
of agricultural production.
Separate cards for single women: Single adult women who live with our without
dependents, as well as old people, who live with relatives by blood or marriage under
the same roof, should be treated for purpose of all food schemes as separate families.
Specifically this means that single adult women and old people will be eligible for
separate ration cards, even if they live under the same roof and share the same
kitchen. This will assure them of greater dignity and autonomy. The same would of
course apply to bonded workers who may stay with their employers.

Fixing the APL quota: The norm for the release of APL quota should be transparent
and realistic, and should be based on population and poverty. Some states, such as
Bihar, Jharkhand and UP are not being given the APL quota on the ground that they
did not take it in the past when the market price was low. This policy favours the
southern states which have been subsidising the APL quota out of state funds, and
punishes the poorer states.
Abolish APL quota - One of the main reasons for the black marketing of the APL
quota is the fact that GOI does not release the full quota based on the number of APL
cards, which gives the dealer the leeway to refuse supplies on the ground that the
limited quota has already been distributed. A better option is to increase the number
of BPL cards from 78 to 120 million, and abolish the APL category. Including AAY,
this policy would cover almost 70 to 75 per cent of the population. If the entitlement
is reduced to 25 kg per card, the total requirement of foodgrains would be 14.5*12*25
=43.5 mT, which is the present level of annual procurement, and hence feasible.
Small amounts can always be imported, whereas there should be complete ban on
exports, except basmati rice. In its place, private traders should be allowed to import
broken rice to stabilise the market price of rice.
Eliminating ghost ration cards — All card holders must be photographed, and their
details along with their photographs should be in the public domain. This will make it
easy for the civil society or consumers to check the list.

There should be only one annual order from a district indicating quota of each
dealer. This way the dealer does not have to wait every month for the district to issue
allotment order. The district office should also issue just one order in the beginning of
the year in which the quota of all the dealers can be mentioned.
Making it obligatory for dealers to sell non-cereal items: Dealers should be asked
to improve their viability by selling items of mass consumption other than wheat and
rice, as in Gujarat.

47

Selecting FPS dealer: In many states the selection needs approval by the Minister or
a committee of MLAs and thus the process is highly subjective and opaque. The FPS
dealership should be allotted to people who are already running a viable shop in the
area. This will ensure that the shop remains open on all working days.

Reduce control of inspectors over shops: Whereas government should set up and
strengthen transparent arrangements for social audit, it may be desirable to remove
some of the irritants, such as no distribution can take place unless the arrival of the
stock has been verified by the inspector. The inspectors should on the other hand meet
the consumers regularly and collect Report Cards from them regarding the degree of
consumer satisfaction.
Take photographs of the stock in the shop: Inspectors supervising supplies should
be given cheap digital cameras so that they can show the stocks at the FPS along with
that day’s newspaper and consumers, and send it to their superiors with a copy to the
dealer. This would show that the grain had actually reached the shop, which often
does not happen in the rural areas.
Oversight by citizens: There should be quarterly meeting of the dealer with all
consumers which should be attended by senior staff.
Develop grievance redressal mechanism: State Governments should provide a free
toll number, where complaints can be registered online. The entire operation should
be outsourced and web-enabled, so that anyone could see how many complaints have
come from each shop, and how many been satisfactorily disposed off.
Launch a drive to cover the poorest: A large number of homeless and poor living in
unauthorised colonies in urban areas have been denied ration cards. A drive should be
launched in collaboration with civil society to cover them in a timebound manner with
ration cards, preferably AAY cards.
Provide cash subsidy: The economic price of foodgrains in FCI godowns (which is
the cost to government after adding storage and transport) is between Rs 9 to Rs 11
per kg. It is distributed to the consumers at various prices ranging from Rs 2 to Rs
6.50 per kg. Thus the Government spends about Rs 2 to Rs 8 per kg as subsidy on
PDS. Since the entitlement is 35 kg per month, there is a subsidy of Rs 70 to Rs 300
per family per month. In certain urban areas the government should try to give the
subsidy amount as cash to the consumers and ask them to buy grain in the open
market. The female head of the family should be asked to open a bank account and
the amount should be centrally transferred from the bank to her without involving any
intermediary or bureaucracy. The results of the pilot experiment should be carefully
analysed before extending it.
Use e-governance: Banking and Information technologies have advanced rapidly and
should enable governments to bring transparency and speed in all applications without
extra expenditure. In addition, computerisation can help modernise the PDS. A
number of states are already innovating in PDS implementation, and improved
performance can be seen in some cases. Although the introduction of modem tools
such as smart cards may not be a panacea for all the evils, they can solve many
problems particularly that of pilfering and spurious beneficiaries.

5.4 Fighting children fs malnutrition
In 1993 the country evolved National Nutrition Goals for the year 2000. These
included reduction by one-half of severe and moderate malnutrition among young

48
children; reducing the incidence of low birth weight below 10 per cent, eliminating
blindness due to vitamin A deficiency; reducing iron deficiency anaemia in pregnant
women to 25 per cent; reducing iodine deficiency disorders to 10 per cent; producing
250 million tonnes of foodgrains; and improving household food security through
poverty alleviation programmes. However these goals were not well disseminated,
with the result that failure to achieve them did not attract criticism either in the
legislatures or in the press.
While there have been some real success stories (Tamil Nadu), in most cases there is
sufficient evidence to show that for fighting child malnutrition the GOI’s main early
child development intervention, the Integrated Child Development Services (ICDS)
programme, has not succeeded in making a significant dent in reducing child
malnutrition. Tamil Nadu, for example, spends Rs 732 on every malnourished child
annually, and West Bengal only Rs 36, which together with Rajasthan and Madhya
Pradesh account for half the malnourished children in 12 major states.

I

The ICDS, the main outlet for public spending on child nutrition, has been in
existence since 1975. It operates through centres in villages, called anganwadi, where
local workers provide nutrition and health services. While the government provides
salaries for the anganwadi staff, state governments are responsible for procuring food
for supplemental nutrition feeding (SNP). However, since 2005, as a result of
Supreme Court direction, the GOI meets half the cost of SNP.
Despite a three-fold increase in its budget by GOI in the last five years and the
contention of the Ministry of Women and Child Development that there are 1.5NCOS
Centres per village now, according to the 61st round of the National Sample Survey
carried out in 2005, the ICDS is reaching only 12.5 per cent children in the age group
6 months to 6 years. As the Centre is likely to be located in the richer part of the
village it may be unable to reach vulnerable children in poorer households and lower
castes and those living in remote areas. The programme targets children mostly after
the age of three when malnutrition has already set in. It does not focus on the critical
age group of children under three years, the age window during which health and
nutrition interventions can have the most effect. Finally, ICDS faces substantia
operational challenges, such as lack of monitoring.
The focus of ICDS should be health and nutrition education, encouraging women to
breastfeed exclusively for six months and after that add semi-sohd family food four to
six times a day in appropriate quantities for the infant, which alone can improve e
child’s nutrition levels. The ICDS should be made a true health, nutrition and
development programme and not limited to a food dole programme. For nutrition to
improve, proper breastfeeding and complementary feeding must be ensured, together
with complete immunization and the prompt management of any illness.
We propose the following measures to improve the ICDS.
Shift focus to under two years: There should be increased spending on infant and
young child nutrition during the first 24 months when malnutrition is frequent and
disturbs the very foundation of life and development. The percentage of underweight
children (moderate and severe) in 2005-06 by age is shown m Figure 8, clearly
showing that malnutrition starts setting in quite fast among children aged 6-12
months, and that adequate precautions need to be taken at that age, otherwise
malnutrition tends to become irreversible.

49
Figure 9: Percentage of underweight children by age

50 -i

45.

44.9

45.6

44.8

45 -

40.2
40 34.7

36.7

35 -

29.5

30
25 20

<6
6-8
9-1 1
12-17
18-23 24-35 36-47
48-59
months months months months months months months months

As already stated (Table 14), only 46 per cent of babies under the age of six months
are exclusively breastfed. Each Centre should be given a target to increase this
percentage to 90-100 per cent, and this should be monitored by independent sources.
Severe malnutrition: Rehabilitation facilities like the Nutrition Rehabilitation
Centres should be available at the PHC level in each district for children suffering
from Grade 3 or 4 malnutrition, and their mothers. ICDS workers should be
responsible for identifying such children and referring them to rehabilitation facilities.

Minimum infrastructure: Each Centre should have the minimum infrastructure and
equipment required for effective delivery of ICDS services. A checklist of minimum
facilities including weighing scales, storage arrangements, drinking water, cooking
utensils, medicine kits, child-friendly toilets, a kitchen shed, and toys should be drawn
up.
Cooked food: For children aged 3-6 years, the supplementary nutrition programme
(SNP) should consist of two hot cooked meals (breakfast and lunch) prepared at the
Anganwadi, based on local foods and with some variation in the menu on different
days of the week. ICDS should learn from the success of mid-day meals programme
that runs fairly well even in states not known for efficiency, whereas the supply of
packaged food in the ICDS programme even in efficient states is not popular with the
children, besides leading to grand corruption in the procurement of packaged food.
Take-home rations: For children below the age of three years, nutritious and
carefully designed locally prepared take-home rations (THR) based on locally
procured food should be recommended, but there could be centre specific variations.
The budget for weaning foods should be suitably enhanced.
Nutrition counselling: Supplementary nutrition should always be combined with
extensive nutrition counselling, nutrition and health education, and home-based

50
interventions (such as boiling water before drinking) for both growth and
development, particularly for children under three.

Local involvement: The scheme will succeed only when the panchayats and other
community groups have sufficient involvement and control over the programme,
including the selection of workers. In some states, the ICDS worker is appointed by a
committee headed by the local MLA. This must change, and powers be given to the
gram sabha (the council of all village adults).
Grading AWCs: The GOI should introduce accreditation of AWCs based on well
defined and transparent criteria through a consultative process by involving
panchayats, mothers’ committees, and community groups. Some experiments have
been done on Himachal Pradesh and Orissa which recognise good performance and
reward them.

Adolescent girls: The programme components need to be expanded and sharply
defined. First and foremost is the universal screening and weighing of adolescent
girls. After screening, there is a need for evaluating these adolescent girls according to
the 10-15 years age category, 16-19 age category and pregnant girls. Then they should
be weighed regularly, and given appropriate nutritious food containing all the desired
micro-nutrients and iron. A similar initiative is needed for all women.
Special category of children: The children of migrant workers should be admitted
and permitted to avail all the facilities and services in the ICDS, regardless of their
place of origin, with no paper work required by their parents or guardians. Data
should be disaggregated at the ICDS level for enrolment and actual coverage, to
reflect the numbers and proportion of disabled children; and children from vulnerable
local SC and ST minority communities; and poor coverage should be penalised.

Expanding the programme: State governments should be directed to fully cover
urban slums within two years. In urban areas, the ICDS should develop prefabricated
structures, to enable it to function in unauthorised slum settlements, or construction
and brick kiln sites.
In rural areas, care should be taken to locate ICDS centres on priority within one year
in all the settlements of PTGs and the discriminated SC settlements, without any
ceiling of minimum children; and all other hamlets with more than 50 per cent SC or
ST or minority population within a maximum of 2 years. In all these centres, the
ICDS staff should be local from the discriminated communities, and two hot meals
should be served instead of one to children of 3 to 6 years; and double weaning foods
should be given to children below 3 years.
ICDS centres should extend their nutrition and health services which at present cater
to expectant and lactating mothers, also to all categories of single women, recognising
them to be intensely nutritionally vulnerable.
Learn from international experience: Thailand has been one of the most
outstanding success stories of reducing child malnutrition in the period 1980-1988
during which child malnutrition (underweight) rate was effectively reduced from 50
per cent to 25 per cent. This was achieved through a mix of interventions including
intensive growth monitoring and nutrition education, strong supplementary feeding
provision, high rates of coverage ensured by having high human resource intensity,
Iron and Vitamin supplements and salt Iodisation along with primary health care. The
programme used community volunteers on a huge scale (one per 20 children), and
involved local people, to instil self-reliance and communicate effectively with target

51

groups. Communities were involved in needs assessment, planning, program
implementation, beneficiary selection, and seeking local financial contributions but
central government control was kept over resource allocation, to ensure a coherent
national programme.
This has significance for nutrition programmes in India as the levels of per capita
GDP, proportion of women in agricultural workforce and child malnutrition rates
around 1980 in Thailand were similar to what we have in India in 2008.
It is absolutely crucial that the multidimensional nature of malnutrition be recognised
and reflected in ICDS implementation: food intake is only one determinant of child
nutritional status. It is however necessary, as it attracts children to other components
of the programme. Therefore in addition to supplementary feeding, state resources
should also be redirected towards improving the delivery of other ICDS services.
Supplementary feeding should be expanded and used strategically, i e, as an incentive
for poor and malnourished children and their mothers, so that they receive health and
nutrition education interventions.

5.5

Mid Day Meal Scheme (MDM)

The Mid Day Meal Scheme (MDM) provides a free cooked meal to every child in
classes I-V of government, government aided and local body schools. This is a
primarily centrally assisted scheme with the state governments contributing partially
towards the cooking costs.
Under the Mid Day Meal Scheme that was launched by the Central Government in
1995, the Government of India provided only free foodgrains while the cooking costs
were entirely borne by the state governments. It was seen however that, many State
Governments/ UT Administrations resorted to distributing food grains, rather than
providing cooked mid day meals because they were unable to provide adequate
funding for meeting the cooking costs. Under orders from the Supreme Court (see
section 6) the scheme was revised in September 2004 to provide cooked mid day meal
with 300 calories and 8-12 grams of protein to all children studying in classes I - V in
Government and aided schools. Some states have extended the scheme to cover
children in the upper primary schools.
The scheme is generally considered to be a great success, though there are problems.
In 2005-2006, only 76.8 per cent of the grain allocated for the mid-day meal scheme
was actually taken by the state governments. Since the allocations are based on
estimates of enrolments and attendance, this means that either not all
institutions/children were covered under the mid-day meal scheme or that the quality
of the mid-day meal was compromised in the sense that not enough quantity of food
was given to the children or that mid-day meal was not provided on all working days.

A clear order was passed by the Supreme Court on April 20th, 2004 stating that
preference must be given to SCs and STs in the appointment of cooks and helpers.
However, only about half of the appointments are from that category.
CAG25 has recently audited the scheme and found that many states resort to over­
reporting the enrolment while projecting the requirement of funds. There is no system
of cross checking the enrolment data furnished by the state governments. In most
states the children were not administered micro nutrient supplements and de-worming
25 Performance Audit on National Programme for Nutritional Support to Primary Education (Midday
Meal Scheme), Report no. PA 13 of 2008, available at cag.gov.in

(WT' 1

52
medicines. The provisions for programme evaluation and regular monitoring and
inspections in the scheme design were not effectively followed nor were the results
analysed for review of errors and introduction of changes on the basis of lessons
learnt. The Ministry failed to put in place an effective system to ensure that teachers
are not assigned responsibilities that would interfere with their teaching activities.
Many instances of the teachers spending considerable teaching time in supervising the
cooking and serving of meals were noticed, resulting in loss of teaching hours.

The CAG recommended that the Ministry needs to establish a system to ascertain the
improvement in nutritional levels of the children. The Ministry should coordinate with the
state governments and ensure maintenance of health cards in all the schools to monitor
the health status of the children.
The Supreme Court Commissioners have made the following recommendations in
their Seventh Report26 submitted in 2008.


Currently the mid-day meal is provided only to children who are attending
schools, whereas the most vulnerable children in the school going age are out
of schools working as child labour, street children etc. The mid-day meal
should be expanded to cover all children in the school-going age, irrespective
of whether they are enrolled in school. The location of the meal served can
continue to be the school, this might further encourage those out of school to
join schools.



The provision for cooking costs under the mid-day meal should be increased
to Rs 3 per child per day (not including foodgrains costs) from the current Rs
2 per child per day in order to be able to provide a nutritious and filling meals
to children. Further this norm should be inflation-linked, in the sense that it is
constantly reviewed based on the price indices.



Mid-day meals should be linked with nutrition education and related
educational activities. State governments should be encouraged to adapt their
textbooks for this purpose, as the NCERT has already done for some
textbooks. Nutritious items such as eggs and green leafy vegetables should be
provided regularly.



Proper infrastructure for mid-day meals should be mandatory, including
cooking sheds, storage space, drinking water, ventilation, and utensils.



Serious action should be taken in the event of any form of social
discrimination in mid-day meals, such as discrimination against Dalit children
or Dalit cooks.
Priority should be given to disadvantaged communities (especially Dalits and
Adivasis) in the appointing cooks and helpers. All cooks and helpers should be
paid no less than the statutory minimum wage.





Community participation in the monitoring of mid-day meals should be
strengthened, particularly to prevent corruption and ensure quality.



Mid-day meals should be integrated with school health services, including
immunization, deworming, growth monitoring, health checkups and
micronutrient supplementation.

26 http://www.sccommissioners.org/

53
The orders of the Supreme Court are awaited.

5.6 Tribals and hunger
As pointed out in various sections of this paper, tribal groups are the worst sufferers
from malnutrition and hunger. They live in agriculturally depressed areas, remote
from roads, and the reach of administration and government programmes is weakest
there.
A civil society organization (CEFS 2005) covered a sample of 1000 randomly
selected tribal households from 40 sample villages in Rajasthan and Jharkhand and
found that 25.2 per cent of surveyed tribal households reported not having two-square
meal in the week before the survey. Of the surveyed tribal households 24.1 per cent
did not have two square meal in the month before the survey and around 99 per cent
of the tribal households were not able to manage two square meal at some point of
time (at varied level) during the previous year.

From the viewpoint of policy, it is important to understand that tribal communities are
vulnerable not only because they are poor, assetless and illiterate compared to the
general population; often their distinct vulnerability arises from their inability to
negotiate and cope with the consequences of their forced integration with the
mainstream economic, social, cultural and political system, from which they were
historically protected as the result of their relative isolation. Post-independence, the
requirements of planned development brought with them the spectre of dams, mines,
industries and roads on tribal lands. With these came the concomitant processes of
displacement, both literal and metaphorical - as tribal institutions and practices were
forced into uneasy existence with or gave way to market or formal State institutions
(most significantly, in the legal sphere), tribal peoples found themselves at a profound
disadvantage with respect to the influx of better-equipped outsiders into tribal areas.
The repercussions for the already fragile socio-economic livelihood base of the tribals
were devastating — ranging from loss of livelihoods, and land alienation on a vast
scale, to hereditary bondage (Saxena and Farrington 2003).
As tribal people in India perilously, sometimes hopelessly, grapple with these tragic
consequences, a small clutch of official programmes has done little to assist the
precipitous pauperization, exploitation and disintegration of tribal communities.
Tribal people respond occasionally with anger and assertion, but often also in anomie
and despair, because the following persistent problems have by and large remained
unattended to:



Land alienation



Indebtedness



Government monopoly over Non-Timber Forest Products (NTFPs)



Ineffective implementation of Panchayats (Extension to the Scheduled Areas) Act
of 1996 for Schedule27 V areas



Involuntary displacement due to development projects and lack of proper
rehabilitation

27 Regions with significant tribal population in Central India have been specifically mentioned in the
fifth Schedule of the Constitution, and have been provided with some safeguards, which however have
not worked well because of political and administrative apathy.

54


Shifting cultivation

Extremists groups are active and normal administration does not function in at least
one-third of tribal blocks in central India.
Apart from policy failures listed above, tribals have also suffered because of the poor
quality of governance. Programme implementation has deteriorated everywhere in
India, but more so in tribal areas, where government servants are reluctant to work,
and are mostly absent from their official duties. The government seems to have
surrendered to political pressures from the staff, as many of their positions have now
been officially transferred from tribal regions to non-tribal regions, where they can
draw their salaries without doing any work! It is a pity that massive vacancies exist in
tribal regions in the face of acute educated unemployment in the country.

Subsistence agriculture, gathering of non-timber forest produce and wage labour are
the main sources of livelihood among tribal people. They are concentrated in the least
developed, rain-fed, undulating and often in remote hilly regions of the country,
largely untouched by ‘green revolution’. Thus, while landlessness is relatively low
among tribal people compared to other poor communities, agriculture productivity is
low and other farm-based avenues, such as dairy and horticulture are also poorly
developed, leading to widespread food insecurity.

Rather than discuss these issues, however crucial they may be, for lack of space, we
will end this section by giving a few suggestions for improving their livelihoods.
First, launch watershed development programmes in uplands, where most tribals live.
In a successful watershed programme the poor benefit in three ways. First, as net
sown area and cropping intensity increases more opportunities for wage employment
are created, which may also increase the wage rate besides the number of days of
employment. Second, increased water availability and reduced soil erosion increases
production on small and marginal farmers’ lands. And last, higher productivity of
CPRs improves access of the tribals to more fodder, fuelwood, water and NTFPs.

Two, start a drive to plant fruit trees on degraded forests and homestead lands that
belong to or have been allotted to the tribals. This will not only make the poor
people’s diet more nutritious, but will also diversify their livelihoods and reduce
seasonal vulnerability.
Three, their work guarantee should be extended through an amendment in the
NREGA to 150 days.
And lastly, promote civil society action in these districts, not only because the reach
of administration is limited, but also because tribal societies are more homogeneous
and respond well to the calls for collective action, which will improve their social
capital, which is so necessary for the success of many government programmes.
6

Supreme Court intervention

In April 2001, the Peoples’ Union for Civil Liberties (PUCL), a human rights
organization, filed a Public Interest Litigation (PIL) in the Supreme Court of India
arguing that the right to food is a fundamental right of all Indian citizens, and
demanded that the country’s gigantic food stocks (about 50 million tonnes of grain at
that time) should be used without delay to prevent hunger and starvation. It argued
that the right to food should be seen as a corollary of the fundamental “right to life”
(Article 21 of the Indian Constitution), in so far as it is impossible to live without
food. Supreme Court hearings have been held at regular intervals since, and the case

55

has attracted wide national and international attention. Although the final judgment is
is
still awaited, significant “interim orders” have been passed from time to time.
For instance, the Supreme Court has passed orders directing the Indian government
to:
(1) Introduce hot cooked mid-day meals in all primary schools.
(2) Provide 35 kgs of grain per month at highly subsidized prices to 15 million
destitute households under the Antyodaya (AAY) component of the PDS.

(3) Double the resource allocations for Sampooma Grameen Rozgar Yojana (India’s
largest rural employment programme at that time, now superseded by the
Employment Guarantee Act).
(4) Universalize the Integrated Child Development Services (ICDS) by increasing the
number of centres from 0.6 million to 1.4 million.

(5) Identify SC and ST hamlets/habitations for new ICDS centres on a priority basis.

Realizing the impact that lapses in implementation have on the well-being and even
the survival of poor people, the Supreme Court in an interim order dated 28
November 2001, converted the benefits of nine food-related schemes into ‘legal
entitlements’ and directed all the State governments to fully implement these
schemes.
The initial petition focused on the drought situation prevailing at that time, especially
in Rajasthan, but the litigation now has a much broader scope. The main concern is to
put in place permanent arrangements to prevent hunger and starvation. The Court
itself noted in an interim order dated 2 May 2003, that ‘reference can also be made to
Article 4728 which inter alia provides that the State shall regard the raising of the level
of nutrition and the standard of living of its people and the improvement of public
health as among its primary duties’.
The Supreme Court appointed two Commissioners, Dr. N.C. Saxena and Harsh
Mander (also a former IAS officer), for the purpose of monitoring the implementation
of the interim orders. The Commissioners present periodic reports to the Supreme
Court. These typically deal with the implementation of Supreme Court orders. In
addition these reports attempt to highlight issues that need further directions from the
Court. These are based on extensive correspondence with governments, reports from
the Commissioners’ Advisors, interaction with citizens organisations, and field visits
made by the Commissioners. So far, eight reports and a few interim reports have been
submitted. They are a rich source of information on the food situation in India, the
implementation of interim orders, the functioning of various schemes, and so on. The
reports also include detailed recommendations to the Court.
Experience shows that Court’s orders have been a useful tool for action. First and
foremost, this is an opportunity to hold the state accountable. Court orders can also be
28 Article 47 (Duty of the State to raise the level of nutrition and the standard of living and to improve
public health) directs that ‘The State shall regard the raising of the level of nutrition and the standard of
living of its people and the improvement of public health as among its primary duties and, in particular,
the State shall endeavor to bring about prohibition of the consumption except for medicinal purpose of
intoxicating drinks and of drugs which are injurious to health.’ The limitation has been that unlike the
Fundamental Rights, which are unambiguous, the Directive Principles of state policy (of which Article
47 is a part) have moral rather than legal binding.

1

56
used to help people to understand that they are entitled to certain forms of public
support as a matter of right. And lastly, governments on their own have started giving
higher priority to the monitored schemes and have often improved the design in order
to increase the coverage of the schemes. For instance, the number of old age
pensioners has been doubled and the scale of pension has increased from Rs 75 per
month to Rs 20029 per month. Several improvements have been made in the contents of
MDM, and in 2006, the calorie content has been increased from 300 calories to 450
calories and the protein content from 8-12 grams to 12 grams.
On the other side, the interim orders are far from being fully implemented, primarily
because of poor delivery structure and weak implementation capacity. For instance,
the Court directed that the AAY cards should be given to the following30:
(1) Aged, infirm, disabled, destitute men and women, pregnant and lactating destitute
women
(2) Widows and other single women with no regular support
(3) Old persons (aged 60 or above) with no regular support and no assured means of
subsistence
(4) Households with a disabled adult and no assured means of subsistence

(5) Households where due to old age, lack of physical or mental fitness, social
customs, need to care for a disabled, or other reasons, no adult member is available to
engage in gainful employment outside the house
(6) Primitive tribes.
However, in actual practice the commissioners have found gross violation of these
orders, and there are serious errors of omission and inclusion, as shown in Table 20.
Lapses have been reported to the Court, and twice the Court summoned and pulled up
the States’ Chief Secretaries. On the whole, the case has certainly enhanced the
profile of the hunger related schemes, and administrators at all levels give a much
higher priority to these schemes than ever before.
Whereas there has been a remarkable improvement in conditions since the case
commenced, the highly uneven performance of the majority of state governments
confirms that the achievement of assured food security of all people, especially
vulnerable social groups, cannot be left to executive discretion alone. It must become
a judicial legal entitlement binding on every government, union, state and local, if the
enormous human suffering, indignity, economic and social cost and enduring injustice
associated with entirely preventable food denials and malnutrition is to be overcome,
and hunger banished from every home in the country.
7

Improving accountability

The Indian state implements massive food, livelihood and social security programmes
- some of the largest in the world - which theoretically support vulnerable people
from even before their birth to their survivors after death. Expectant mothers are fed
in ICDS centres, along with infants, children up to the age of six, and adolescent girls.
Children in school get school meals. As adults, women receive maternity support,
29 This is only the central government’s contribution. States are encouraged to add to the amount, with
the result actual pension amount varies from Rs 200 to Rs 500 per month.

30 Most of the people in these categories suffer from chronic hunger.

J

t

57
bread earners are guaranteed 100 days of wage employment in public works; and if
identified as poor, they can buy subsidised cereals from a massive network of half a
million ration shops. The aged - and in many states widows and disabled people - are
given pensions. And if an earning adult dies prematurely, the survivor is entitled to
insurance.
These programmes are plagued by corruption, leakages, errors in selection, delays,
poor allocations and little accountability. They also tend to discriminate against and
exclude those who most need them, by social barriers of gender, age, caste, ethnicity,
faith and disability; and State hostility to urban poor migrants, street and slum
residents, and unorganised workers. Therefore, not only do we need to identify the
destitutes and run special programmes for them, but improve monitoring and
accountability for all programmes that impinge on hunger.

7.1

Destitutes

Government programmes are also woefully inadequate to address destitution; in fact
they tend to be blind to or in denial of the fact that large numbers of people lack even
the elementary means and power to survive with dignity. The government needs to
act, not after there is an emergency like a drought or flood, not even after people die
of starvation, but pro-actively before people slip into destitution, and fail to access the
nutritious and culturally appropriate food they require to lead healthy lives.

Identification: One feature which is common to public policy relating to the
dispossessed groups31 is the fact that for almost all, there is very little authentic
official data, about their numbers and lists. This is not a chance or random default. It
is the outcome of what we describe as ‘invisibilisation’ of these powerless people by
the state. We therefore recommend an effort at least once every two years to not just
estimate these groups, but to conduct a full listing. This should be undertaken in each
district of the country, led by the state government and district collectors, but with
active participation of local bodies such as gram sabhas and municipalities,
professionals, experts, civil society groups and representatives of these populations.
These lists should be updated every two years, and should form the basis for them to
receive the due entitlements.
Free food: All old people from the neighbourhood should be permitted to share in the
school mid-day meal of hot cooked food in schools or ICDS centres without any
conditions, as practiced in the state of Tamil Nadu. This serves as a last defence
against starvation of the aged destitute, without requiring any additional
administrative costs.
Establish community kitchens across cities and urban settlements to provide
inexpensive, subsidised nutritious cooked meals near urban homeless and migrant
labour settlements, with committed source of external funds (preferably government
funded or in partnership with civil society: both citizens and private sector), which are
managed by community groups of homeless people, preferably women, and will
provide employment as cooks to homeless people themselves (at least 50 such
kitchens per city with population more than one million; and 100 with populations
more than one million, and 500 in those more than ten million).

Residential care for food security of most vulnerable children: For children of
rural seasonal migrants, the village school should be converted into a community
31 The six categories are mentioned in section 6.

<

58

based temporary residential school, to enable the child to access food and education,
without having to migrate every year with their guardians. The aged of the village,
who are often left behind in destitute conditions, may take care of the children in
return for sharing the food in the community based hostels. This model has been
adopted by the Orissa government for the Bolangir district, and is recognised
internationally as a best practice, applauded among others by Dr Amartya Sen.
For children who still migrate, it should be the duty of the education department of the
host state to provide education in local language at work sites, and permit the child to
access midday meals at the nearest government school. This is again a best practice
adopted by the governments of Andhra Pradesh for migrant families from Orissa.
For children who live and work on the streets, the only way to secure their right to
food (and with this their rights to education, health and protection), is to provide them
alternatives to move decisively away from the streets and any kind of work. This is
possible only through guarantees of comprehensive long tenn care in open voluntary
residential homes. Every city would need a large network of such schools. This could
be done by converging the Sarva Shiksha Abhiyan (a programme to bring every child
to schools) and the Women and Child Department’s night shelter programmes, as well
as Labour Department programmes for child workers, to pool resources to create
hostels for urban street and working children, and greatly enhancing allocations. This
best practice has been adopted by the governments of Andhra Pradesh and Delhi. The
aim should be in the first phase of three years to start at least 100 such centres in all
metropolises; and 50 in all other urban areas of population more than half a million.

7.2

Problems of delivery and implementation

Outlays should not be considered as an end in itself. Delivery of food based schemes
requires increasing financial resources, but more importantly the quality of public
expenditures in these areas. This in turn requires improving the governance,
productivity and accountability of government machinery. Some suggestions are:
Shift from input controls to monitoring of outcomes: Officials at all levels spend a
great deal of time in collecting and submitting information, but these are not used for
taking corrective and remedial action or for analysis, but only for forwarding it to a
higher level, or for answering Parliament or Assembly Questions. Often data on
performance reaches late, or is not available district-wise, or is ‘doctored’, with the
result that accountability cannot be enforced. For instance, we do not have district­
wise figures on IMR, MMR, malnutrition, or poverty. Had this data been available
every year and for each district, it would have been easier to fix responsibility and
help in outcome monitoring.
It is not enough that the central government departments and the state governments
use professional and academic organisations to undertake impact studies from time to
time. Their findings must be publicised and discussed with key stakeholders so that
improvements in design and delivery can be effected at the earliest. Governments
should also put on its website findings of the impact studies, and distribute these in
the workshops it organizes. Dissemination of results is critical for use.
Assess quality: There are unfortunately no indicators for assessing the quality of
programme outcomes. GOI and civil society may like to fill this void and produce
reports that assess the quality of outcomes. For instance, one would like to know how
many newly constructed toilets are being used, and what impact it has had on peoples’
health and hygiene.

59
Measure absenteeism: While satisfaction may be subjective, and with economic
progress people’s aspirations for high quality services may have increased,
quantitative data on absenteeism of both service providers and service receivers
(number of days the ration shops open, or women turning up for institutional
deliveries) throws a great deal of light on the quality of service. For instance, a study
of Rajasthan indicated that 45 per cent of doctors were absent from PHCs, and 56 per
cent of the time sub-centres were closed. Worse, the patterns of absences and facility
closures were essentially unpredictable, so people could not plan their visits.

Social audit: Governments should introduce social audit by assessing the experience
of the people service providers are intended to serve. With community participation,
the evidence should be collected from stakeholders, so as to promote accountability,
equity, effectiveness, and value for money. Such an audit will supplement
conventional audit and will often provide leads to it. A financial audit aims at making
organizations accountable to the government and to the legislature. A social audit
makes them accountable to their stakeholders especially in relation to the social
objectives.

Promote public private partnership: The role of the private sector in social sector is
not sufficiently recognised in India. For instance, most health care is now given in the
private sector and, for the poor, by very poorly or untrained practitioners. Rather than
trying to replace private services, the Government should try to improve the private
market, with the carrot of training and the stick of public information. Public funds
should be increased to combating communicable diseases and providing health
insurance cover to all.
Link performance to fiscal transfers: Very little of the GOI’s annual transfers to the
states (roughly Rs 3,000 billion, not including subsidies, such as on food, kerosene,
and fertilizers) is linked with performance and good delivery. The concept of good
governance needs to be translated into a quantifiable annual index on the basis of
certain agreed indicators such as infant mortality rate, extent of immunisation, feeding
programmes for children, availability of safe drinking water supply, malnutrition,
rural and urban unemployment, the percentage of girls married below 18 years,
percentage of villages not connected by all weather roads, and so on. Once these
figures are publicized states may compete to improve their score. Central transfers
should be linked to such an index.

Conclusion
In the ultimate analysis, the constraints to reduction in hunger are rooted in bad
policies, faulty design, lack of appropriate monitoring and evaluation, poor
governance and lack of political will. Action is needed on all the fronts. Economic
growth alone is insufficient to bring about significant reductions in the prevalence of
malnourishment among children, or increase in food intake of the poor. Without a
major shake up in policy and an improvement in the effectiveness of its
implementation, the attainment of the MDGs by India in this regard looks extremely
unlikely.
Development is an outcome of efficient institutions rather than the other way around.
Focus therefore must be shifted from maximising the quantity of development
funding to maximising of development outcomes and effectiveness of public service
delivery. Concerted policy action is needed to improve the hunger indicators of the
marginalised groups, women and children, and of the 300 million poor increasingly

1

60

concentrated in the poorer states. This requires additional resources, as well as better
policies and sound delivery mechanisms. Unless ration shops open and distribute
food, doctors attend health centres and provide health care, and incentives for them to
do so are not perverse, a mere increase in the social sector expenditure would only
result in further leakages and swelling the already non-functional parasitic
bureaucracy.

4

*

61

8 Abbreviations
Antyodaya Anna Yojana
AAY
Above Poverty Line
APL
Anganwadi Centres
AWCs
Body Mass Index
BMI
Below Poverty Line
BPL
Comptroller and Auditor General of India
CAG
chronic energy deficiency
CED
Common Property Resources
CPR
Oppressed, refers to the ex-untouchables
Dalits
Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations
FAO
Food Corporation of India
FCI
Gross Domestic Product
GDP
Global Hunger Index
GHI
Government of India
GOI
Integrated Child Development Services
ICDS
International Food Policy Research Institute
IFPRI
Infant Mortality Rate
IMR
low birth weight
LBW
Millennium Development Goals
MDG
Mid Day Meal Scheme
MDM
monthly
per capita expenditure
MPCE
Minimum Support Price
MSP
Metric Tons
MT
NABARD National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development
National Family Health Surveys of India
NFHS
Non Governmental Organization
NGO
National Nutrition Monitoring Bureau
NNMB
National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme
NREGS
National Rural Health Mission
NRHM
National Sample Surveys of India
NSS
other backward castes
OBC
Public Distribution System
PDS
Purchasing Power Parity
PPP
primitive tribal groups
PTGs
Reproductive & Child Health
ROH
Rural Electrification Corporation
REC
Rural Infrastructure Development Fund
RIDE
scheduled-castes
SC
Small Scale Industries
SSI
scheduled tribes
ST
United Nations Development Programme
UNDP
Women and Child Development (Department of)
WCD

ft

A

62
9

Bibliography

Ahluwalia, Montek S 1978: Rural Poverty and Agricultural Performance in India, Journal of
Development Studies, April

Ahmed, Akhter U., Ruth Vargas Hill, Lisa C. Smith, and Tim Frankenberger 2007: The
World’s Most Deprived: Characteristics and Causes of Severe Poverty and Hunger, October,
IFPRI, Washington

Arnold F, Nangia Parveen, Kapil Umesh 2004: Indicators of Nutrition for Women and
Children Current Status and Recommendations. Economic and Political Weekly, XXXIV7:
14-20.
Bajpai Nirupam, Jeffrey D. Sachs, and Nicole Volavka 2005: India’s Challenge to Meet the
Millennium Development Goals, CGSD Working Paper No. 24, April, Working Papers
Series Centre on Globalization and Sustainable Development, The Earth Institute at Columbia
University www.earth.columbia.edu

Bardhan Pranab K. 1985 Poverty and "Trickle-Down” in Rural India: A Quantitative
Analysis, http://www.ifpri.org/pubs/books/Mellor85/Mellor85ch08.pdf
Bhalla, G.S. and Peter Hazell 2003: Rural Employment and Poverty: A Strategy to Eliminate
Rural Poverty within a Generation, Economic and Political Weekly, August 16-22, Vol.
XXXVIII, No 35.

Bisaliah, S. 2007: Capital Formation In Indian Agriculture; Growth, Composition,
Determinants And Policy Directions Asian Development Bank

Black, R.E, Allen, L.H, Bhutta, Z.A et al 2008: Maternal and child undemutrition: Global and
regional exposures and health consequences. The Lancet 371: 243-60.
CEFS 2008: Key Findings of the Survey Research on Hunger and Poverty iin Adivasi Areas of
Rajasthan and Jharkhand, Centre for Environment and Food Security, New Delhi
Chand, Ramesh 2007: Wheat Import and Price Outlook for 2007-08; Separating the Grain
from the Chaff, December 29, Economic & Political Weekly
Chand, Ramesh 2007a: Demand for Foodgrains, Economic and Political Weekly December
29
Chand, Pamesh 2008: The Global Food Crisis: Causes, Severity and Outlook Economic &
Political Weekly June 28
Gopaldas, Tara 2006: The Problem of hidden Hunger and Possible Interventions, Economic
and Political Weekly August 26,

Deaton Angus and Jean Dreze 2008: Nutrition in India: facts and interpretations, Princeton
University,

Economic Survey, 2007-08: Finance Ministry, GOT
GOI 1993: ‘Report of the Expert Group on Estimation of Proportion and Number of Poor’,
Perspective Planning Division, Planning Commission, New Delhi.
GOI 1979 Government of India 1979: Report of the Task Force on Projection of Minimum
Needs and Effective Demand, Perspective Planning Division, Planning Commission, New
Delhi.
GOI 2005: Evaluation of the TPDS, PEO, Planning Commission, New Delhi

Griffin, K. 1974: The Political Economy of Agrarian Change London: Macmillan.
Himanshu 2007: Recent Trends in Poverty and Inequality: Some Preliminary Results,
Economic and Political Weekly February 10

63

IFPRI 2008: The India State Hunger Index: Comparisons Of Hunger Across States Pumima
Menon, Anil Deolalikar, Anjor Bhaskar, October 14, New Delhi
Jha, Praveen 2007: Some Aspects of the Well-Being of India’s Agricultural Labour in the
Context of Contemporary Agrarian Crisis
Jha, Shikha, PV Srinivasan, and Maurice Landes 2007: Indian wheat and rice sector policies
and the implications of reform. Economic research report no. 41 (United States. Dept, of
Agriculture)
Jose Sunny, K Navaneetham 2008: A Factsheet on Women’s Malnutrition in India, Economic
and Political Weekly, Aug 18

Krishnaraj, Maithreyi 2006: Food Security, Agrarian Crisis and Rural Livelihoods,
Implications for Women Economic and Political Weekly December 30,
Kumar, A K Shiva 2007: Why Are Levels of Child Malnutrition Not Improving? Economic
and Political Weekly, April 14
Kumar, Praduman, Mruthyunjaya, Madan M Dey 2007: Long-term Changes in Indian Food
Basket and Nutrition Economic and Political Weekly September 1

Kumaran M., 2008: Hunger and Under-Nutrition in Post-Liberalisation Rural India - A
Review, Dissertation, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi
Kundu, Amitabh 2006: ‘Food Security System in India: Analysing a Few Conceptual Issues
in the Contemporary Policy Debate’ in Nisha Srivastava and Pravesh Sharma eds, Protecting
the Vulnerable poor in India: The role of social safety net’ WFP, New Delhi
Lanjouw, Peter and Rinku Murgai 2008: Poverty Decline, Agricultural Wages and Non-Farm
Employment in Rural India: 1983-2004
Lipton, M. with Longhurst, Richard 1989: New Seeds and Poor People ,London: Unwin
Hyman
Mander, Harsh 2008: Living with Hunger: Deprivation among the aged, Single Women and
people with Disability, Economic & Political Weekly April 26,
Mehta, Aasha Kapur and Amita Shah 2002: ‘Chronic poverty in India: Overview study Defining the nature of chronic poverty in India’, Mimeo, Chronic Poverty Research Centre,
UK.
Mittal, Surabhi 2008: Demand-Supply Trends and Projections of Food in India, Working
Paper No. 209, March ICRIER, New Delhi

Navaneetham K 2008: A Factsheet on Women’s Malnutrition in India Sunny Jose, Economic
& Political Weekly Economic & Political Weekly August 16,
NNMB. 2006: National Nutrition Monitoring Bureau. Reports Hyderabad: National Institute
of Nutrition,. 1979-2006. Available from: http://www.nfhsindiaorg/nfhs2.html
NSSO 2007: ‘Perceived Adequacy of Food Consumption in Indian Households 2004-2005NSS 61St Round, July 2004- June 2005’, NSS Report No. 512, National Sample Survey
Organisation, Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation, Government of India,
New Delhi.

Palmer-Jones Richard and Amaresh Dubey: Poverty Measurement, Poverty Lines and
Consumer Price Indexes in India: A Critique

Palmer-Jones, R and Dubey, A, 2008: Poverty Incidence in India since 1993: Another View,
Working Paper 08, DEV Working Paper Series, The School of Development Studies,
University of East Anglia, UK.

64
Patnaik, Utsa 2004: The Republic Of Hunger, Public Lecture on the occasion of the 50th
Birthday of Safdar Hashmi, organized by SAHMAT Safdar Hashmi Memorial Trust on April
10,, New Delhi

Patnaik, Utsa 2007: Neoliberalism and Rural Poverty in India, Economic & Political Weekly
July 28

Planning Commission 2006, Mid-term Evaluation of the Tenth Plan, New Delhi
Planning Commission 2008: Eleventh Five Year Plan, volume 2, New Delhi
Ramachandran, Nira 2007: Women and Food Security in South Asia: Current Issues and
Emerging Concerns, www.geocities.com/wduminder/healthinsouthasia

Ramachandran, Prema 2007: Poverty nutrition linkages, Indian J Med Res 126, October 2007,
pp 249-261
Ramachandran, Prema 2008: Changing Food Consumption Patterns in India, Bulletin of the
Nutrition Foundation of India, Volume 29 Number 2, April
Roy Raj at 2008: Endemic Hunger in West Bengal, Economic & Political Weekly May 3

Saxena N.C. 2004: Right to food - Supreme Court Intervention, in M.S. Swaminathan &
Pedro Medrano ed, From Vision to Action, Madras
Saxena N.C. 2004: Synergizing Government Efforts for Food Security, in M.S. Swaminathan
& Pedro Medrano ed, From Vision to Action, Madras
Saxena N.C. and John Farrington 2003: Trends and Prospects for Poverty Reduction in Rural
India: Context and Options, Working Paper 198, Overseas Development Institute, London

Sen Ilina 2004: Hunger in Urban India Economic and Political Weekly October 9,

Sen Pronab 2005: Of Calories and Things: Reflections on Nutritional Norms, Poverty Lines
and Consumption Behaviour in India,, Economic and Political Weekly October 22

Sen, Abhijit and Himanshu 2004: Poverty and Inequality in India-Widening Disparities
during the 1990s, Economic and Political Weekly, Sept 18 and 25
Shatrugna, Veena 2001: The Nutrition Scenario - Micronutrient supplements in the absence
of adequate proteins and calories — A Review; National Institute of Nutrition, Hyderabad
Sundaram K 2007: Employment and Poverty in India, 2000-2005 Economic and Political
Weekly July 28,

UNDP 2007: People’s participation in generating District Human Development Report Cards
PAHELI: New Delhi
UNDP 2008: Study on perception of disadvantaged in seven states of India, August, New
Delhi

UNICEF 2007: State of the World’s Children 2007.
Weismann D, Sost AK, Schoeninger I, Dalzell H, Kiess L, Arnold T, Collins S. 2007: ‘The
Challenge of Hunger 2007: Global Hunger Index: Facts, determinants, and trends. Measures
being taken to reduce acute undernourishment and chronic hunger’. International Food Policy
Research Institute, Concern.

World Bank 2007: Social Protection for a Changing India, Human Development Unit, South
Asia World Bank, New Delhi

k

Position: 4640 (1 views)