12357.pdf

Media

extracted text
WORKING PAPER



(M

ontract Farming for
Agricultural Development
Review ofTheory and Practice
with Special Reference to India

Centre for Trade & Development

An Oxfam GB Initiative

Contract Farming for
Agricultural Development
Review of Theory and Practice with
Special Reference to India

Sukhpal Singh
Centre for Management in Agriculture
Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad

Copyright © Centad March 2005

Centad Working Papers are intended to disseminate the preliminary find­
ings of ongoing research both within and outside Centad on issues around
trade and development for the purpose of exchanging ideas and catalysing
debate. The views, analysis and conclusions are of the authors only and
may not necessarily reflect the views or position of Centad or Oxfam GB.
Readers are encouraged to quote or cite this paper with due acknowledge­
ment to the author and Centad.

Design and Printing by
New Concept Information Systems Pvt. Ltd.
Plot No. 5, Institutional Area, Sarita Vihar
New Delhi- 110 076

Foreword

Contract farming is fast emerging as a very prominent issue in agriculture, especially in the
context of globalisation and liberalisation. The advent of globalisation and liberalisation has
intensified the role of the agribusiness firms who are entering into contract with primary
producers and farmers for supplying raw materials. There are diverse views on the merits
and demerits of contract farming. Many argue that since the primary producers or the
farmers lack the bargaining capacity to negotiate the contract, they often end up on the
losing side by entering into contracts that are detrimental to their interests. There are also
arguments to suggest that if contract farming is rooted in appropriate policy, statutory and
institutional framework, it has tremendous potential to help the agricultural community in
general and the small and marginal farmers in particular.
This paper addresses all these issues by exploring the basic economic rationale of contract
farming and the existing practices and their implications. The nature and the practice of the
'contract' are central to the issue of contract farming. The paper argues that it is of utmost
importance to cogently draft the contract with apposite pricing clauses to protect the ben­
efits of the primary producers and farmers. The need to have a comprehensive statutory
protection from ill effects of contract farming for the farmers also need not be overempha­
sised. The paper also points out the need to strengthen the agricultural co-operatives, the
Non Governmental Organisations (NGOs) and the civil society, so as to enable them play a
prominent role in protecting the interests of farmers in contract farming.

It is expected that the analysis in this paper will be useful for policy-makers, researchers
and the civil society. Any suggestions or feedback on the paper would be welcome.

Samar Verma
Regional Policy Advisor
Oxfam GB

Abbreviations

ACC

:

Appachi Cotton Company

AoF

:

Association of Farmer

APMC

:

Agricultural Produce Market Committee

AoP

:

Association of Persons

BILT

:

Ballarpur Industries Limited

CCI

:

Cotton Corporation of India

CGG

:

Community Grower Group

GAP

Green Agro Pack

Gol

Government of India

HLL

Hindustan Lever Limited

ICICI

Industrial Credit and Investment Corporation of India

IFC

International Finance Corporation

rrc

Indian Tobacco Company

MNCs

Multi National Corporations

MoU

Memorandum of Understanding

MSSL

Mahindra Shubhlabh Services Limited

NABARD

National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development

NDDB

National Diary Development Board

NGOs

Non Governmental Organisations

NGCs

New Generation Co-operatives

PAFC

Punjab Agro Foodgrains Corporation

PAIC

Punjab Agro Industries Corporation

RKKs

Rallis Kissan Kendras

SAP

Structural Adjustment Programme

SBI

State Bank of India

SHG

Self-help Group

TICA

Tobacco Industry Control Authority

UB

United Breweries

UPASI

United Planters Association of South India

USAID

US Agency for International Development

UTI

Unit Trust of India

Contents

Foreword

Hi

Abbreviations

iv

Executive Summary

vii

1.

Introduction

1

2.

The Logic of Contract Farming

2

3.

Nature of Contracts and Growers

5

3.1

4.

5.

6.

Understanding Contracts

5

3.2

Nature of Contracts

5

3.3

Nature of Contract Growers

6

Practice and Implications of Contract Farming

7

4.1

Firms and Contract Growers

4.2

Impact on Peasantry and Labour

8

4.3

Equity and Efficiency

9

4.4

Effect on Food Markets and Non-Contract Growers

9

4.5

Social and Economic Differentiation

10

4.6

Effect on Environment and Gender

10

4.7

Contracting and Local Organisations

11

The Indian Experience in Contract Farming

12

5.1 Corporate-led Contract Farming

12

7

5.2

Practice of Contract Farming in India

5.3

Changing Dynamics of Contract Farming in India: The Consortium Approach 14

5.4

State-led Contract Farming

16

Conclusions and Policy Suggestions

19

14

List of Figures
Figure 1: Bi-partite contract farming model

13

Figure 2: Tri-partite contract farming model

13

Figure 3: The quad-partite contract farming model

15

Figure 4: The five-partite CF in India

17

Figure 5: State-led contract farming system in Punjab

18

List of Tables
Table 1: Relative benefits of alternative marketing structures for small farmers

References

20
22

Execotnve Smimmairy

Contract farming refers to a system wherein,
a farmer/primary producer agrees to supply a
pre-agreed quantity/acreage of a certain quality/
variety produce at a pre-agreed price and time,
to a processing/marketing firm (a known buyer).
It is also known as outgrower scheme, and sat­
ellite farming. The contracts could be only pro­
curement arrangement or resource providing as
well. The relevance and importance of each type
varies from crop/product to product over time
and these types are not mutually exclusive.
A farmer may prefer a contract due to:
» access to additional sources of capital,
° a more certain price,
o access to new technology and inputs.
For a processor or distributor, contracts:
° make smaller demands on scarce capital
resources,
o are an alternative to costly and risky cor­
porate farming,
o provide an access to unpaid family labour
and a route to make use of State funds
directed at farmers by development
agencies.



®




°

°








At a more macro-economic level, contracting
can help remove market imperfections in pro­
duce, capital (credit), land, labour, information
and insurance markets. But, contract farming is
viewed, in political economy terms, as one mode
of capitalist penetration of agriculture for capital
accumulation and exploitation of farming sector
by the agribusiness companies.
The review reveals that in most of the situa­
tions:
• The contracts are highly biased against the
growers,
• Firms favour large farmers and relatively
better endowed regions,

Companies work with small farmers only
when the area is dominated by small farmers
or they are dictated/encouraged by the state
or the nature of the crop,
There is 'agribusiness normalisation' in con­
tract price over time,
There is little bargaining power of the farmer
due to 'monopsony' of the firm,
Farmers compete with each other to get con­
tracts,
Companies refuse to buy or reject with qual­
ity standards manipulation,
The extension is poor and there is no com­
pensation for crop failure,
Small farmers are excluded,
There is inter-locking of markets,
Higher costs are passed on to the farmers,
There are bribes/cheating by company offi­
cials and 'tying of contracts',
Labour conditions are poor and exploitative
in terms of wage rates, gender discrimina­
tion, use of child labour, and causal employ­
ment,
Contracts encourage 'reverse tenancy',
Contracting has serious equity and efficiency
implications,
Contracting also leads to food insecurity,
social and economic differentiation, and
ecological degradation like over-pumping of
groundwater, salination and chemicalisation
of soil and water.

In India, where contract farming is prevalent
across regions and crops, it has moved from firm­
farmer (two-party) system to tri- and quad-par­
tite arrangement wherein state and its apparatus
have been involved e.g. in Punjab. There have also
been some cases of group contracting. In both,
state and agribusiness models, contract growers
have faced many problems like:
• undue quality cut on produce by firms,
• delayed deliveries at the factory,

delayed payments,
low price and
pest attack on the crop with no compen­
sation.



The reasons for failure of contract farming have
been mainly in the design and the management
of the projects by the companies and their part­
ner institutions. The model has moved onto the
franchisee route more recently. Whereas compa­
nies are sharing their risk with other companies/
intermediaries and banks, the farmer's risk is not
being shared.







The above discussion suggests that it is not the
contract perse which spells hardship or doom for
growers, particularly small growers as a system,
but how it is practised in a given context. In fact,
all over the world, contracting of some kind is a
necessity for modern commercial agriculture due
to the wide support for contract farming under
the SAP and the international and national com­
petitive pressures in agribusiness sector world­
wide. Contract farming has the potential to lead
to a betterment of all the parties, especially the
small and marginal farmers, if it is promoted and
undertaken judiciously and if there can be cer­
tain mechanisms in place.

The lessons and mechanisms are:
• Contract farming need not be promoted for
all crops, and there is no single model suit­
able for all conditions but a series of alterna­
tives.
• Contracts require frequent and independent
scrutiny so that they remain competitive both
with similar contracts and with open market
transactions.













Vigorous bargaining co-operatives or other
agricultural producer organisations are needed
to negotiate equitable contracts. A New Gen­
eration Co-operative (NGC) is the need of the
hour.
A legal protection to contract growers as
a group is a must to protect them from illeffects of contracting.
There can also be a quasi-judicial system at
the local level to monitor the contracts and
resolve any conflict with appropriate penal­
ties to any of the defaulting parties. A gen­
eral code of conduct for both the parties in
order to avoid conflicts and breaking down of
contracts can help.
A careful examination and design of the pric­
ing and other aspects of the contracts and
a reduction in the number of intermediaries/parties in contracts is required in India.
Preferably, it should be a farmer-company
arrangement.
State agencies and NGOs should intervene in
contract situations as intermediaries to pro­
tect the farmer and broader local community
interests.
Companies and state should promote group
contracts with the intermediation of local
NGOs and other organisations and institu­
tions so that contractual relationships are
more durable, enforceable, and fair.
An insurance component in contract farming
interventions is a must to protect the farmer's
interest.
The most important thing is to ensure market
for the farmer produce at better price and to
build trust with small and timely steps.

1. Introduction

The developments in the field of marketing, food
habits, technology, and agriculture in the new
economic environment have brought about a
new arrangement in raw material production and
procurement known as contract farming. Under
the contract system, a farmer agrees to supply a
pre-agreed quantity of a certain quality produce
at a pre-agreed price and time, to the processing
or marketing firm, which may or may not provide
certain facilities like provision of inputs, finance,
etc. This is happening as good quality, timely
raw material is a pre-requisite for any success­
ful agribusiness firm, whether operating in the
domestic or international market. It is important
to recognise that this reorganisation or restruc­
turing of the agricultural production sector is
taking place due to policy and market changes
outside the sector i.e. in the industrial and trade
sectors, and, these macro-policy changes drive
micro-changes like contract farming which have
the potential to change the production structure
and relations of production in the agricultural
sector. As a part of the internationalisation pro­
cess in agriculture which involves production,
capital, and trade, contract farming encom­
passes all the three dimensions through inter­
vention in input supply and production decisions,
supply of capital and finance, and global market­
ing of agro-products. In fact, it is nothing but an
extension of the phenomenon of global sourcing
wherein a firm can produce anything anywhere,
by sourcing inputs from anywhere, to be sold in
any market in the world.

The proponents of agribusiness promotion argue
that contract farming leads to big jumps in
incomes and employment in agriculturally back­
ward regions and brings a break from low levels
of productivity and instability in production, thus
putting the local economy on a dynamic path of
growth and development. This is possible not
only because of the technological and capital
resources of these firms, but also because of the
international character of agribusiness processes,
which gives access to international markets. The

agribusiness firms take risk by undertaking new
projects in processing and marketing and provide
a stream of cash flow to the local economy. This
brings not only benefits to the local economy but
also helps earn foreign exchange and increase food
supply nationally and locally (Williams and Karen,
1985; Leisinger, 1987; Benziger, 1996). Contract
farming has also been used to promote new high
value crops which are more input intensive, risky,
high-tech, and market dependent for profitabil­
ity, to lower costs either by yield improvement
or cutting input costs through better extension,
and to raise returns by value addition to primary
produce (Benziger, 1996; Singh, 2002). However,
it is important to recognise the role of the state
in encouraging or discouraging the agribusiness
firms and in protecting the producers in contract
situations (Asano-Tamanoi, 1988; Christensen,
1992; Grosh, 1994; Benziger, 1996). There is also
a need to look at the potential role of agribusiness
more specifically for different commodity sectors
and regions, and not as a blanket solution since
there are certain sectors which may require a
more effective public sector or state intervention
especially in technology and institutional inno­
vations, instead of a private agribusiness effort
(Christensen, 1992).

But, looking at agribusiness growth from a differ­
ent perspective (political economy) makes it clear
that it is nothing but a process of industrialisation
of agricultural and rural production which takes
place through simultaneous processes of appropriationism and substitutionism. Whereas appropriationism operates as a process of exploitation
of land and other biological sources of supply by
the application of modern and advanced technol­
ogy to get more and cheaper raw materials, sub­
stitutionism operates as a process which tries to
move industry or agribusiness away from direct
and linear dependence on crop and other direct
sources of raw materials by way of application of
technology to create new products and sources
of products. Thus, the two processes are con­
tradictory to each other though they are driven

Contract Farming for Agricultural Development

Contract farming is more like
the practice of subcontracting
in industrial sector where the
large firms can farm out many
production activities to small firms
and benefit from lower costs and
better skills.

by the same agribusiness sector and forces. Fur­
ther, the application of biotechnology accelerates
these processes and leads to what can be called
bio-industrialisation (Goodman et al., 1987). In
fact, contract farming directly promotes the pro­
cess of appropriationism. Further, contract farm­
ing is more like the practice of subcontracting in
the industrial sector where large firms can farm
out many production activities to small firms and
benefit from lower costs and better skills (Wilson,
1986; Watts, 1992; White, 1997).

Given the failure of government mechanisms to
support agriculture, and wide support for con­
tract farming under the Structural Adjustment
Programme (SAP) and liberalisation policies
everywhere, in the presence of promotion of

contract farming by the international develop­
ment agencies like the World Bank, the USAID,
the IFC and the CDC (Little and Watts, 1994;
White, 1997), it is inevitable that new forms
of contracts will be tried by the agribusiness
firms as it is the only way to ensure quality
and timely availability of raw material for pro­
cessing, especially when, in some countries like
India, captive farming is not allowed legally
under Ceilings on Land Holding Act. Besides,
captive farming means putting large resources
in raw material production which may not be
the best economic option for many agri-busi­
ness firms especially small scale ones. Since
contract farming also leads to changes in
the way agricultural production, processing
and marketing are organised (White, 1997),
it is important to understand its practice and
dynamics. This paper examines the logic of
contract farming (section 2), and its practice
and implications from the producers' and the
local economy's point of view with the help of
an exhaustive review of various strands of lit­
erature (section 3). It also discusses the Indian
experience of contract farming (section 4) and
concludes by examining some possible alterna­
tive institutional mechanisms to use contract­
ing as a developmental vehicle (section 5).

2. The Logic of Contract Farming
Contract farming can be defined as a system for
the production and supply of agricultural and hor­
ticultural produce by farmers/primary producers
under advance contracts, the essence of such
arrangements being a commitment to provide an
agricultural commodity of a type, at a specified
time, price, and in specified quantity to a known
buyer. In fact, contract farming can be described
as a halfway.house between independent farm
production and corporate/captive farming and
can be a case of a step towards complete ver­
tical integration or disintegration depending
on the given context. It basically involves four
things - pre-agreed price, quality, quantity or
acreage (minimum/maximum) and time. From
a developmental intervention point of view, it

Review of Theory and Practice with Special Reference to India

is a situation in which the relationship between
the agribusiness firm and the farmers takes the
form of an expert endowing the apprentice with
resources, knowledge and skills. Or alternatively,
it is more a case of bringing the market to the
farmers which is navigated by agribusiness firms
(Christensen, 1992). Contract farming is known
by different variants like centralised model which
is company-farmer arrangement, outgrower
schemes, which is run by government/public
sector/joint venture, nucleus-outgrower scheme
involving both captive and contract farming by
the contracting agency, multi-partite arrange­
ment involving many types of agencies, inter­
mediary model where middlemen are involved
between the company and the farmer, and satel­

lite farming referring to any of the above models
(Eaton and Shepherd, 2001; Gol, 2003). In
fact, contract farming varies depending on the
nature and type of contracting agency, technol­
ogy, nature of crop/produce, and the local and
national context.

Contracts could be of three types; (i) procure­
ment contracts, under which only sale and
purchase conditions are specified; (ii) partial
contracts, wherein only some of the inputs are
supplied by the contracting firm and produce is
bought at pre-agreed prices; and (iii) total con­
tracts, under which the contracting firm supplies
and manages all the inputs on the farm and
the farmer becomes just a supplier of land and
labour. The relevance and importance of each
type varies from product to product and over
time these types are not mutually exclusive (Hill
and Ingersent, 1987; Key and Runsten, 1999).
Whereas the first type is generally referred to as
marketing contracts, the other two are types of
production contracts (Scott, 1984; Welsh, 1997).
But, there is a systematic link between product
and factor markets under the contract arrange­
ment, as contracts require definite quality of pro­
duce and, therefore, specific inputs (Scott, 1984;
Little and Watts, 1994). Also, different types of
production contracts allocate production and
market risks between the producer and the pro­
cessor in different ways.
Contract farming emerged as an important phe­
nomenon in the developed countries of the West
during the 1950s and the 1960s. By 1980, about
one-third of the total US farm output, and as
much as 100 percent of poultry meat, milk and
certain vegetables, was produced under con­
tracts (Little and Watts, 1994). Even in Tasmania
island of Australia, by the mid-1990s, 95 percent
of the potato production was under contracts
compared to almost nil in the 1950s (Fulton and
Clark, 1996). On the other hand, in the devel­
oping countries, the Multi-National Corporations
(MNCs) brought in the system of contract farm­
ing during the late 1970s and the early 1980s.
Besides private and multinational enterprises,
contract farming is also practised by statal and
parastatal agencies in many countries in differ­

ent commodity sectors like tea production in
Kenya, tobacco and livestock in Thailand, rubber
in Malaysia, coconut in Indonesia, palm oil in
the Philippines, and seed in India (Nanda, 1995;
White, 1997; Shiva and Crompton, 1998).

The production, marketing and distribution of
agricultural products are becoming increasingly
sophisticated for several reasons. Firstly, modern
advances in technology have made it feasible for
agricultural products to be produced to 'specifi­
cation' and preserved in a fresh condition. Sec­
ondly, the optimum scale of operations has been
increasing, especially in processing and distribu­
tion. Thirdly, new selling methods have emerged
emphasising a brand image based on consis­
tent quality. On the demand side, due to rising
incomes, consumers are becoming increasingly
discriminating in their tastes, especially about
the timing of production and marketing, and
the quality of products. This increased sophis­
tication in consumer demand gives an added
impetus to the search for ways of improving the
co-ordination of production, processing and dis­
tribution, especially with respect to timing and
quality control (Hill and Ingersent, 1987). In fact,
value addition is increasingly taking place in the
upstream stages of the agribusiness chain, as
the downstream stages have been more or less
exhausted so far as quality and value of product
are concerned. This provides a strong rationale,
from the demand side, for contract farming as a
means of raw material supply.
For different reasons, both farmers and farm
product processors/distributors may prefer con­
tracts to complete vertical integration. A farmer
may prefer a contract which can be terminated
at reasonably short notice. Also, contracting
gives access to additional sources of capital, and
a more certain price by shifting part of the risk

Contract farming varies depending
on the nature and type of contracting
agency, technology, nature of crop/
produce, and the local and
national context.

Contract Farming for Agricultural Development

3

extension system is unable to help farmers
adapt/meet these standards (Allen, 1972 as
quoted in Hill and Ingersent, 1987, p. 169).

of adverse price movement to the buyer (Hill
and Ingersent, 1987). Farmers, also get access
to new technology and inputs through contracts
which otherwise may be outside their reach. For
a processor or distributor, contracts are more
flexible in the face of market uncertainty, make
smaller demands on scarce capital resources,
and impose less of an additional burden of
labour relations, ownership of land, and produc­
tion activities, on management (Buch-Hansen
and Marcussen, 1982; Kirk, 1987). The firm
even gets an access to unpaid family labour
(White, 1997) and can make use of state funds
indirectly through agricultural production sector
which are directed at farmers by development
agencies (Clapp, 1988). Also, food processors
can minimise their overhead costs per unit of
production by operating their plants at or near
full capacity as contracting gives assured and
stable raw material supplies from farms. The
firm can also project an image of working with
local producers as a partner when it undertakes
contract farming and may even obtain statal and
international agency incentives for its activities
as developmental projects, instead of corporate
farming (Kirk, 1987). Allen (1972) identifies cer­
tain pre-conditions for development of contract
farming practice i.e. (a) Producers geographi­
cally concentrated in an area/s, which is rela­
tively distant from the final market, so that bulk
assembly prior to distribution in retail outlets
is a necessary condition of efficient marketing;
(b) Producers not shielded by government price
support or a strong producers' organisation, so
that significant scope exists for reducing uncer­
tainty regarding supplies and prices; (c) Buyers
demand rigorous grading standards but exist­
ing standards (govt./producer) are inadequate
or incapable of upgrading, and (d) Agricultural

From an institutional economic perspective,
the logic for contract farming could also come
from the creation of positive externalities like
employment, market development or infra­
structure, if agribusiness firms create them
better than the open market or the state (Key
and Runsten, 1999). In other words, can con­
tract farming help people other than those who
have direct stakes and pay for it? Contract farm­
ing figures as an institutional arrangement for
agricultural development in the fields of inputs,
product exchange, and product upgrading,
the last referring to research and innovations
(Christensen, 1992).

Contract farming is also seen as a
way to reduce costs of cultivation
as it can provide access to better
inputs and more efficient production
methods. The increasing cost of
cultivation was the reason for the
emergence of contract farming in
Japan and Spain in the 1950s.

However, a political economy view of contract
farming rejects its benefits to consumers and
farmers and argues that contracts develops only
when there is diminished role of the state in
agriculture, increased specialisation of agricul­
tural production processes, and the agricultural
markets like farm produce or credit become less
competitive or inefficient (Wilson, 1986). In fact,
it argues that contract production is one mode

'_________ 4

Review of Theory and Practice with Special Reference to India

At a more macro-economic level, contracting
can help remove market imperfections in pro­
duce, capital (credit), land, labour, information
and insurance markets; facilitate better co-ordi­
nation of local production activities which often
involve initial investment in processing, exten­
sion etc.; and can help in reducing transaction
costs (Grosh, 1994; Key and Runsten, 1999). It
has also been used in many situations as a policy
step by the state to bring about crop diversifi­
cation for improving farm incomes and employ­
ment (Benziger 1996; Singh, 2000). Contract
farming is also seen as a way to reduce costs
of cultivation as it can provide access to better
inputs and more efficient production methods.
The increasing cost of cultivation was the reason
for the emergence of contract farming in Japan
and Spain in the 1950s (Asano-Tamanoi, 1988)
and in the Indian Punjab in the early 1990s
(Singh, 2000).

of capitalist penetration of agriculture for capital
accumulation and exploitation of farming sector.
This leads even to processes of'self-exploitation'
of the farmers, and the companies gain indirect
control of land. The political economy approach
rejects the various rationale of contracting like
perishability of produce, specialisation of a
crop, capital intensity of production etc. as it is
the social relations of production which deter­
mine these aspects of the production system.
And, product differentiation and monopolistic
tendencies cause contracting (Wilson, 1986).
Though there are many benefits of contract pro­

Contract farming should be
viewed as a cultural and historical
phenomenon rather than as
an imposed legal category of
relationships as these contexts
determine the response of the
farmers to the new arrangement.

duction for the farmers, what happens when
yields stagnate, costs rise and there are open
market gluts?

3. Nature of Contracts and Growers
3.1 Understanding Contracts
Since the system of contract farming has its influ­
ences on the entire local and regional economy,
all producers and organisations have to recog­
nise the intervention of such a system and bear
the consequences. Even for individual farmers,
it is not contract per se but the relationship it
represents, which is crucial as the divergence
between the two may prove crucial in determin­
ing the development of contract farming as an
institution (Clapp, 1988; White, 1997). Further, it
is the context of the contract which can make a
whole lot of difference as there are many actors
and factors in the environment which influence
the working and outcome of contracts and lead
to a culture of contracting which is location and
community specific. The way farmers perceive
contract farming, i.e., define their relationship
with companies, differs in each cultural context
(Asano-Tamanoi, 1988; White, 1997). In fact,
there is so much diversity in the type of firms,
farmers, nature of contracts, crops, and socio­
economic environment that it is better to focus
on specific situation than the generic institution
of contract farming (Little, 1994; White, 1997).
Some others argue that contract farming should
be viewed as a cultural and historical phenom­
enon rather than as an imposed legal category
of relationships as these contexts determine the
response of the farmers to the new arrangement
(Asano-Tamanoi, 1988).

3.2 Nature of Contracts
Contracts differ in their nature and effect due to
the variations in the nature of crops, contract­
ing agencies, farmers, crop technology, and the
context in which they are practised. Even within
a crop, different companies can have different
types of contracts. For example, contract sys­
tems adopted by different seed companies in
India differ in their provisions as far as relation­
ship with farmer is concerned (Shiva and Cromp­
ton, 1998). A review of evidence reveals that
farming contracts are generally oral or unwrit­
ten, if written then in non-local language, and
are quite loose in their specifications. For exam­
ple, seed companies in India do not have written
contracts, and do not even guarantee a price,
though the farmer is assured of a profit in terms
of seed being bought at a rate higher than the
market price of the grain. Some of them do not
even assure of the purchase of seed (Shiva and
Crompton, 1998). Only a delivery slip or a credit/
seed/seedling slip is the proof of the contract a
grower has.
Contracts are highly biased against the growers.
The company obligations are not specified. The
contracting agencies end up rejecting low qual­
ity produce without any compensation for the
grower, and the defaulters, on the other hand,
are expelled from future contracts. Firms favour
large farmers for various reasons, discussed in

Contract Farming for Agricultural Developmpnt

the following paragraphs, and finally large farm­
ers also become dependent on these firms due
to large volumes of produce they grow (CDC,
1989; Little and Watts, 1994). In Jamaica, the
state Tobacco Industry Control Authority (TICA)
guaranteed a minimum price of tobacco before
planting, paid for the produce delivered within
two weeks, deducted all input costs from the
payment for the produce, and distributed bonus
as and when warranted, under contracts. On
the other hand, the MNC (CCJ) worked with
selected growers including former company
employees, provided all the inputs, and had
total control over farming operations, though it
did allow diversified cropping by the growers
and ensured farmer participation in manage­
ment of contracts through grower committees
(Lewis, 1985).
Plantation contracts are much more stringent in
that the quality standards are tough, companies
control plantations, and a very early advance
notice (three years) is necessary to withdraw
from contracting for both the parties. The com­
pany can refuse to procure produce and the
growers are not even allowed to grow food crops
(Sachikoyne, 1989; Porter and Phillips-Howard,
1995). Generally, grower's fixed price is the price
formula followed in most contracts, though there
are other possibilities like processor's fixed price,
sharing of profits between firm and farmers, and
administered prices which are rarely practised
in contract situations (CDC, 1989; Little and
Watts, 1994).

3.3 Nature of Contract Growers
Contract farming may involve medium or large
capitalist farmers relying on wage labour, small
peasant producers who depend, to a larger

Contract farming may involve
medium or large capitalist farmers
relying on wage labour, small
peasant producers who depend to
a larger or smaller extent on family
labour, and even landless who lease
in land for contract production.

6

Review of Theory and Practice with Special Reference to India

extent on family labour, and even landless who
lease in land for contract production as was the
case in Thailand and India (USAID, 1994; Singh,
2002). But, agribusiness corporations tend to
prefer large farmers for contract farming because
of their capacity to produce better quality crops
due to the efficient and business-oriented farm­
ing methods, large volumes of produce which
reduces the cost of collection for the firm, their
capacity to bear risk in case of crop failure, and
various services provided by these large produc­
ers like transport, storage, etc. (Wilson, 1986;
Winson, 1990; Key and Runsten, 1999). This
happened in Australia where the MNCs started
working with only large producers and ratio­
nalised the grower numbers as soon as the
government withdrew from contract regulation.
Also, the companies resorted to growers groups
and group contracts to reduce farmer freedom
to hold multiple contracts which was prevalent
earlier (Burch and Pritchard, 1996). As a result
of contracting, the number of potato growers
declined from 7000 in 1950s to just 550 in the
1990s (Fulton and Clark, 1996).

On the other hand, small farmers are picked
up by firms for contracts only when the area
is dominated by them, there is government
directive to do so or they are found to be
low cost producers in certain areas and crops
(CDC, 1989). Further, firms may work with
small farmers to make use of the state sup­
port (financial and technical) to these produc­
ers under various development programmes
(Glover and Kusterer, 1990), and to benefit
from lower cost production on these farms as
these farmers have access to cheaper family
labour, and being residual claimants of their
labour, work more conscientiously than hired
labour (Key and Runsten, 1999). Companies
often engage local procurement agents, NGOs,
and state agencies as intermediaries to pro­
cure and to enforce contracts respectively
(Clapp 1988; and USAID, 1994). In fact, some
of them even use large growers, rural elite,
and local small processors as sub-contrac­
tors to procure from the small growers for the
company (Kirk, 1987). The seed companies in
India use small companies as sub-contractors

to procure seeds produced under contracts
(Shiva and Crompton, 1998).

In Canada, small tomato growers were preferred
as the crop required hand-picking which only
small farmers do as the large ones do mechani­
cal harvesting, especially when weather limits
the use of mechanical harvesters (Winson,
1990). Similarly, in India, gherkin contract farm­
ing is carried out by small and marginal farm­
ers as the crop requires plenty of labour inputs
which these farming families can provide from
within (Dev and Rao, 2004). Also, working with
many small farmers in the case of small pro­
cessors gives the required flexibility in procure­
ment schedule helping to extend the processing
season and use the equipment efficiently, and
helps spread risk of supply failure as compared

Contracting helped farmers
become better farmers, gave
more reliable incomes, generated
employment especially for women,
provided new skills of farming
and did away with patron-client
relationship between large and
small producers.

to working with a few large farmers. Further,
the small producers are at a greater risk work­
ing with small processors as these processors
could go broke quicker than the large ones, in
the face of competition and restructuring of
markets (Winson, 1990).

4. Practice and Implications of

Contract Farming
The studies of contract farming effects can be
grouped into three broad categories; a) agribusi­
ness management studies which look at con­
tracts only as a management tool and a strategy
to overcome procurement and related business
problems; b) project evaluation studies which
view it as a project and evaluate it in terms of
tangible development objectives of the projects
like income, employment, and technology trans­
fer; and c) political economy studies, which go
beyond the tangible outcomes and look at the
broader production and social relations effects
of the contracting system, in terms of changes
in economic opportunity and welfare of different
classes, and in rural social structures.

4.1 Firms and Contract Growers
Many project evaluation type studies show
that contracting helped farmers become better
farmers, gave more reliable incomes, generated
employment especially for women, provided
new skills of farming, did away with patron­
client relationship between large and small pro­
ducers, and farmers got better help in farming
than without the contract (Glover and Kusterer,

1990, USAID, 1994; Dunham, 1995; Porter and
Phillips-Howard, 1995; Fulton and Clark, 1996;
Singh, 2002). Farmers were also found to switch
between companies for deliveries under contract
as well as to default on the produce delivery
and the relevant use of inputs supplied by the
firm (Christensen, 1992; USAID, 1994; Singh,
2002). But, farmers generally found that the
contract firms provided poor extension service,
overpriced their services, passed on the risk to
the producers, offered low prices of produce,
delayed payments, and did not explain the pric­
ing method (Glover and Kusterer, 1990; Grosh,
1994; White, 1997; Singh, 2002). In fact, con­
tracting in a way reinforces or reintroduces the
phenomenon of 'interlocking of markets' under
the control of firms, which was criticised as an
exploitative mechanism in rural development
literature and something which needed to be
eliminated.

In certain other situations like in Africa, the
farmers faced problems of bribes by company
officials, manipulation of inspection standards
by companies, tying of one contract to another,

Contract Farming for Agricultural Development

7

Though contracts do lead to
increase in income and employment
initially, they may not be stable
and sustainable, and prove to
be costly in terms of use of local
resources in the presence of unstable
international commodity and
product markets.
and outright cheating in accounts (Little and
Watts, 1994; Glover and Kusterer, 1990). On
a larger level, farmers felt that they had little
bargaining power compared to that of the com­
pany which they perceived benefited more than
the farmers in the contracting process, and that
they had become dependent on the firms for
credit and other inputs (Glover and Kusterer,
1990; Fulton and Clark, 1996; Burch, 1996).
There is generally a monopsony of the process­
ing firm in a given area and the contracts are
one-sided i.e. they favour the firm and their
enforcement is carried out very strictly on the
farmers (Kirk, 1987; Grosh, 1994; White, 1997;
Singh, 2002). Further, firms backtrack in times
of surplus produce and do not compensate the
farmers for natural calamity losses (Collins,
1993; Singh, 2002). Due to their unequal bar­
gaining power vis-a-vis a few large buyers or
suppliers, contracting farmers may not be able
to negotiate a 'fair' contract price (Hill and
Ingersent, 1987). But, wherever there have
been collective responses, through co-opera­
tives or farmer groups, to contracting situations
due to the cultural and historical reasons, the
farmers have managed their relationships with
companies well, as in Japan (Asano-Tamanoi,
1988). Contracting leads finally to the worsen­
ing of the relationship between producers and
the firms to the disadvantage of the farmers.
Even the market choices become limited, and
contracting tends to reinforce itself over time.
Finally, how can a contract between a processor
and a farmer be equitable, as the two are not
equal entities? (Wilson, 1986).

Though contracts do lead to increase in income
and employment initially, they may not be stable
and sustainable, and prove to be costly in terms

8

Review of Theory and Practice with Special Reference to India

of use of local resources in the presence of
unstable international commodity and product
markets for which the produce is meant and due
to the way the contracts are practiced (Dunham,
1993; Little, 1994; Dunham, 1995; Torres, 1997).
In the Australian case, the firms were using
local resources for global competition and it was
doubtful whether they will continue to procure
locally. They did not show any concern for the
local economy, as it was only a route to access
Asian markets (Burch and Pritchard, 1996). The
firms also tend to practice "agribusiness normali­
sation" over time which means that they reduce
the prices and other benefits offered to the
growers with which they commence operations,
when the procurement base is created and there
are enough farmers to procure from (Glover and
Ghee, 1992; Burch, 1996; Singh, 2002). Fur­
ther, the contracting farmers are exposed to the
adverse impact of the misjudgement of market
requirements by the firm, and other policy deci­
sions (Hill and Ingersent, 1987; Little and Watts,
1994; Torres, 1997).

Contract farming can lead to change in social
relations of production, in terms of relations
between the farmers and the companies. The
loss of independence, if at all, suffered by the
farmer and the dominance of local production
systems by an outside firm may be counted as
a social cost. The loss of autonomy is espe­
cially pronounced when contract farmers incur
heavy debts with the corporations. The contract
growers in Australia agreed that field officers
exercised significant influence on farmer deci­
sions of tactical nature and more day to day
decisions like use of inputs and timing of har­
vest of crop. Also, farmers become depen­
dent on companies for financial requirements
due to the use of high cost inputs (Fulton and
Clark, 1996).

4.2 Impact on Peasantry and Labour
It is frequently argued that agribusiness in gen­
eral, and contract farming in particular, reinforces
the trend toward proletarianisation of the peas­
antry (Korovkin, 1992) though it is of an incom­
plete or impure character. In the case of peasant
contract farming, the trend towards proletari­

anisation appears in a disguised form, whereby
peasant producers preserve their access to land
but lose their productive autonomy to agri-cor­
porations and become "piece-workers with their
own tools for the job" (Clapp, 1988). In Indo­
nesia, the outgrowers on the contract farming
schemes are referred to, in the official docu­
ments, as "plasma farmers" as against industrial
workers who are known as "black ants" (White,
1997). To reduce their production costs, transna­
tional corporations and capitalist farmers rely on
seasonal rather than stable labour. As a result,
the majority of workers employed in agribusi­
ness are either semi-proletarianised peasants or
pauperised labourers - the rural semi and sub­
proletariat with little or no land and no stable
jobs (Payer, 1980; Clapp, 1988; Little and Watts,
1994). Even the wage rate for the landless work­
ers may be lowered over time due to contract­
ing as workers from outside may in-migrate and
the out-migration may stop from the given area
(Kirk, 1987; Little and Watts, 1994).
Contract farming also reinforces reverse tenancy
wherein small and marginal farmers lease out
land to large and medium farmers who are often
contract growers for the companies as was the
case in the Indian Punjab (Singh, 2002). Further,
the contract farm labour is generally composed
of women and child labour that too female child
labour as they are docile, flexible, and quality
labour besides being low cost (Singh, 2003).

Contracting also leads to monocropping which in
turn leads to deskilling of the farmers and labour
over time as they no longer grow other crops
or the same crop with different local techniques
(Clapp, 1988; White 1997). The companies tend
to prefer monocropping as it is necessary to
meet processing unit needs, gives better con­
trol over farmers and is easy to manage. But,
from farmer's side, this reduces the efficiency
of farmer's other crop initiatives, reduces food
availability, leads to duplication of input services
as farmers have to approach another source for
procuring inputs for the non-contracted crops,
increases farmer risk, leads to underutilisation
of his labour time as each crop has only certain
periods of work requirement, and chances and

implications of the misuse of cash crop money
are high (CDC, 1989).

4.3 Equity and Efficiency
The equity and efficiency implications of con­
tracting is an important economic issue as it
creates asymmetries of both static as well-as
dynamic type. The static asymmetries created by
the monopsony of the firm, incomplete contract
specifications, and crop specific access to inputs
lead to allocational inefficiencies and reduce
grower income, thus creating inequity. On the
other hand, dynamic asymmetries in the produc­
tion contracting arrangement like quality control
exercised by the processor, transfer of skills to
growers, and the relative bargaining power of
the growers lead to very uncertain or unfavour­
able outcomes for efficiency and equity depend­
ing on the local context of the participating grow­
ers, processors, and the markets (Scott, 1984).
Though inequality generated by contract farming
does not create poverty, it can exacerbate exist­
ing poverty (Kirk, 1987; Baumann, 2000).

4.4 Effect on Food Markets and Non-Contract Growers
The effect of contracting on non-contract farm­
ers and the surrounding areas may not always
be positive, and contracting therefore, needs to
be examined in its totality. What is favourable for
the contracting firms and farmers may harm other
actors and sectors of the local economy (Little
and Watts, 1994; Porter and Phillips-Howard,
1995). It is argued by some that contract pro­
duction tends to shift the production in favour
of export-oriented and cash crops at the cost of
basic food crops for the poor. This can lead to
higher prices of the food commodities and prod­
ucts, especially for non-contract farmers and the

Contract farming reinforces reverse
tenancy wherein small and marginal
farmers lease out land to large and
medium farmers who are often
contract growers for the companies
as was the case in the
Indian Punjab.

Contract

labour households who do not benefit from con­
tracting in terms of higher incomes. Even regional
differentiation tends to be increased as the firms
choose relatively better off areas for contracting
(Little and Watts, 1994). The growth of contract­
ing might also reduce the volume of trading in
the open market such that prices may no longer
reflect overall market conditions. In other words,
the open market might become so narrow that
prices may cease to be truly representative of the
total market situation and the contracting farmer
no longer has a reliable benchmark for judging
the fairness of his contract price. But, effective
competition in agricultural markets need not be
reduced by contractual arrangements, provided
firms are competing with each other for the con­
tracts of adequately informed producers (Hill and
Ingersent, 1987).

4.5 Social and Economic Differentiation
It is feared that by favouring the large-scale
farmer, who is better able to meet the exact­
ing requirements of producing to contract speci­
fication, contracting may encourage a socially
undesirable 'dual' agricultural development
(Sachikoyne 1989; Grosh, 1994; Little and Watts,
1994; Dunham, 1995). The agribusiness compa­
nies may follow different contract methods for
different types of farmers for the production of
the same crop. The bigger farmers have con­
tracts which provide for an advance assessment
of produce, fixing of price and payments, as
against the small/poor farmers from whom the
firm picks up only a selected part of the produce
which meets quality standards (Grosh, 1994;
Morvaridi, 1995).

While a majority of impoverished peasants
become progressively proletarianised, a wealthy
minority develops into commercial producers

The growth of contracting might
also reduce the volume of trading
in the open market such that
prices may no longer reflect overall
market conditions.

Review of Theory and Practice with Special Reference to India

(Clapp, 1988). This process can eventually result
in the disintegration of the peasantry, whereby
poor peasants lose all their links with land while
rich peasants develop into peasant capitalists
(prosperous small farmers who combine family
and wage labour). The differentiation is accen­
tuated as contracting offers rich peasants with
an opportunity to incorporate modern technolo­
gies, augment their assets and increase the reli­
ance on wage labour, at the same time acceler­
ating the transformation of poor peasants into
a rural semi-and sub-proletariat (Wilson, 1986;
Kirk, 1987; Korovkin, 1992; Burch, 1996; White,
1997). But, there are others who argue from
their studies of the Kenyan agricultural economy
that contract farming, per se, does not create
a class of rural accumulators as household pro­
duction is sustained only at a subsistence level,
and it does not lead to proletarianisation and
food insecurity, though capitalist relations of
production do develop in contracting contexts,
and a rural bourgeoisie emerges. But, other
pressures from the world economy might lead
to the implications of contracting pointed out by
the dependency school (Buch-Hansen and Marcussen, 1982; Currie and Ray, 1986). The socio­
economic divide between the contracting and
non-contracting farmers could also deepen due
to contracting (Glover and Kusterer, 1990).

4.6 Effect on Environment and Gender
The contracting firms tend to aggravate the
natural resource crisis as most of the contracts
are short term (one or two crop cycles) and the
firms tend to move on to new growers and lands
after exhausting the natural potential of the local
resources, particularly land and water, or when
productivity declines due to some other reason
(Morvaridi, 1995; Torres, 1997). The over-exploi­
tation of groundwater, salination of soils, soil fer­
tility decline, and pollution are typical examples
of environmental degradation due to contract
farming (USAID, 1994; Rickson and Burch, 1996;
Siddiqui, 1998). The firms do not care for this as
the costs of such effects are externalised so far
as the firm is concerned.
The gender effects of contract farming is also
an important area of enquiry. Though, in many

cases, women did not express dissatisfaction
with the contract arrangement and in fact,
reported that the employment under contract
production had given them better self-esteem,
self-confidence and influencing power within
the household (Kirk, 1987; Glover and Kusterer,
1990; USAID 1994; Dunham, 1995; Porter and
Phillips-Howard, 1995; Torres, 1997), contract
farming does lead to gender inequalities both in
the quantity as well as quality of work for women
and children. The women not only end up work­
ing longer hours in the field, as they are consid­
ered better workers and paid less (Collins, 1993),
the burden of off-farm work also falls on them
due to the over-occupation of men with contract
production (Porter and Phillips-Howard, 1997;
White, 1997). Since there is a close connection
between contract system and gender, it affects
gender division of labour and gender relations of
production. There is gendering of tasks in the
field and practice of female child labour (Torres,
1997; Singh, 2003). The gender relations within
the household are affected by way of tension
over contribution by women to contract produc­
tion, and negotiation by women for share in the
contract income (Carney, 1988). This, in turn,
affects productivity of the farm as fields tend
to be neglected and these disputes, being pri­
vate family matters, are difficult to resolve. But,
it is important to recognise that the impact on
women is class differentiated. There have been
instances of collective action by women's groups
over control of contract production and income
(Buloh and Sorensen, 1993).

4.7 Contracting and Local Organisations
Contract farming may have profound organi­
sational implications. Historically, peasants in
Latin American, Asian, and African countries
have relied for their survival on communal
arrangements which spun off various forms of
communal organisations. These organisations
regulated the management of local resources
(natural pastures, woods, and water for irriga­
tion) and defended their members' interests
against outsiders. The growth of contract farm­
ing leading to commercialised sophisticated
export agriculture undermines the communal
arrangements, giving rise to new forms of mass-

The growing importance of contract
farming has serious implications
for the agribusiness co-operatives,
which have been practising some
form of contract procurement in
the past simply because they are
producer-owned organisations.

based rural organisations: labour unions among
agricultural workers, on the one hand, and asso­
ciations defending the commercial interests
of small agricultural producers, on the other
(Clapp, 1988).

The growing importance of contract farming has
serious implications for the agribusiness co-oper­
atives, which have been practising some form of
contract procurement in the past simply because
they are producer-owned organisations. They
will have to now compete with the private and/or
multinational firms at the farmer/producer level
in terms of providing competitive price and other
incentives so that producer members do not
turn away from the co-operative organisation.
This will require more efficient functioning of the
co-operatives. In Australia, the lack of financial
support to co-operatives by the state and the
competition from the MNCs and other local agri­
business firms, under deregulated environment,
led to the closing of some co-operative process­
ing plants and a change in the form of organisa­
tion in others (Burch and Pritchard, 1996).

Also, an agribusiness firm generally does not
encourage the co-operative formation and expan­
sion in its area of operation as it may become
a competitor in the relatively longer term and
spoil the procurement base of the firm (Wilson,
1986). This happened in the case of a Unilever
subsidiary in Cameroon wherein as farmers tried
to organise a co-operative to strengthen their
bargaining power, the company refused to pro­
cure and the crop was wasted. This happened
despite the fact that the co-operative was domi­
nated by large farmers. Finally, the co-opera­
tive failed. However, it is seen that a parastatal
may encourage co-operatives genuinely and

Contract Farming for Agricultural Development

11

if that happens, then they do succeed as well.
This happened in Kenya in case of tea (Konings,
1998). But, the success of the contract system
per se in Kenya.was the result of the coming
together of the state, donors and transnational
capital, favourable market conditions, access to
capital, and a relatively decentralised manage­
ment system (Little and Watts, 1994).
The above review of literature reveals that in
the context of African, Latin American and a
few Asian countries, contract farming has led to

many ill-effects in the spheres of livelihoods of
producers, community organisations and insti­
tutions, environment, and gender. These stud­
ies point out that though the contract system
leads to better incomes and employment in the
beginning, the relations between firms and farm­
ers worsen overtime and the system results in
ecological and economic degradation of local
production systems. Most of the studies, which
are in the context of relatively less developed
regions, find contracts inequitable, short-term,
and ambiguous.

5. The Indian Experience m Contract Farming
The experience of agricultural development in
India has shown that the existing systems of deliv­
ery of agricultural inputs and purchase and use
of agricultural output have not been efficient in
reaching the benefits of better linkages between
agriculture and agro-processing industry to the
farmers or the agro-industry. The timely, qual­
ity and'cost effective delivery of adequate inputs
still remains a dream despite the marketing
attempts of the corporate sector and the devel­
opmental programmes of the state. The farmers
are not able to sell their produce remuneratively.
There is plenty of distress among farmers both in
agriculturally grown as well as backward regions
manifested in farmer suicides. Agricultural markets in India which are found to be inefficient
and imperfect, may not be able to ensure fair
and reasonable returns to all the players. There
are temporal and spatial variations in the mar­
kets and the producers' share in the consumers'
rupee has been quite low in general, except a
few commodities. In fact, in some commodities
like potato in some regions in India, producers
end up making net losses at the same time when
traders make substantial profits from the same
crop (Mitra and Sarkar, 2003). In the environ­
ment liberalisation and globalisation policies, the
role of the state in ;agricultural marketing and
input supply is being reduced, and an increasing
space is-being provided to the private sector to
bring about better marketing efficiency in input
and Output markets. On the other hand, proces­

jl^ Review of Theory and Practice with Special Reference to India

sors and/or marketeers face problems in obtain­
ing timely, cost effective, and adequate supply of
quality raw materials.

5.1 Corporate-led Contract Farming
Contract farming in India is currently being prac­
tised by multinational firms like Cadbury (cocoa),
Pepsi (potato, chillies, groundnut), Unilever
(tomato, chicory, tea, and milk), ITC Ltd. (tobacco,
wood trees, and oilseeds), Cargill (seeds), domes­
tic corporates like Ballarpur Industries Limited
(BILT), JK Paper, and Wimco (in eucalyptus and
poplar trees), Green Agro Pack (GAP) Ltd., VST
Natural Products, Global Green, Interrgarden
India, Kempscity Agro Exports, and Sterling Agro
(all in gherkins), United Breweries (UB) (barley),
Nijjer Agro (tomato), Tarai Foods (vegetables), A
M Todd (mint in Punjab), McCain India (potato in
Gujarat), (Singh, 2000a; Rangi and Sidhu 2000;
Subrahmanyam, 2000; Dileep et al, 2002; Saigal
and Kashyap, 2002; Grewal, 2003), Namdhari
Seeds (seeds), and various government and semi­
government agencies, especially in seed produc­
tion and perishables like vegetables and fruits,
with varying degrees of success with individual
farmers. There are many banks which provide
finance for contract farming. These include
NABARD, SBI, ICICI Bank and UTI Bank. Con­
tract farming in India by the corporate sector has
so far been more of a case of buy back, and input
supply (Figure 1) and/or credit supply or linkage
as depicted in Figure 2.

Figure.1: Bi-partite contract farming model

Supply of inputs on credit

In Tamil Nadu, Appachi Cotton Company (ACC)
has undertaken contract cotton farming with
eight farmer groups from 32 villages in Coim­
batore district for bringing 1050 acres under
cotton contract farming. The contract growers
form an Association of Persons (AoP). The major
features of the model adopted by ACC are: one
village - one SHG, one village - one variety of
cotton, cotton crop insurance, door delivery of
agricultural inputs, crop loans at 12 percent rate
of interest, farm service centres, assured buy
back from farmers though farmers are free to
sell elsewhere if they find prices higher than con­
tract price, contamination control from farm to
factory and synchronised sowing of crop (ITCOT,
2004). The Cotton Corporation of India (CCI) has
gone in for group contracts in Nagpur district of
Maharashtra wherein an Association of Farmers
(AoF) signs a MoU with the CCI which promises
improved yield and lower cost. It promotes single
crop or a variety for a village, especially in cotton,
to take care of the problem of admixture of differ­
ent varieties. It is also popularising concepts like
hand picked cotton to improve quality of produce.
The farmer representatives will monitor cultiva­
tion of contracted cotton in the villages. In 2002,
the CCI worked with 3500 cotton farmers in four
states and achieved an average profitability of
Rs. 25000 per hectare in Bharuch district of Gujarat
and Rs. 10000 per hectare in Andhra Pradesh. In
M. R, it was only able to lower the cost by about
Rs. 2000 per hectare (Deshpande, 2003).
Marico Industries has a tie up with oilseed co­
operatives in Maharashtra for safflower oilseeds

wherein it provides working capital, infrastruc­
tural facilities, managerial inputs, and job work of
crushing the oilseeds to these co-operatives. In
turn, the co-operatives are responsible for getting
contract produced for the company the oilseeds
by their members (Bharadwaj and Palan, n.d.).
In tea, some small companies have undertaken
contract farming under the Tea Board-UPASI
(United Planters Association of South India)
project where they work with Self-Help Groups
(SHGs) of women who supply tea under con­
tracts to the companies and the extension sup­
port is provided by the UPASI. One such company
procures 90 percent of its total tea leaves for
processing into tea from 30 SHGs (Hayami and
Damodaran, 2004). Ion Exchange Enviro Farms
Ltd., a subsidiary of Ion Exchange India Ltd.
undertakes contract farming with Community
Grower Groups (CGGs) having large acreage, on
a profit-sharing basis. Prime Bio Products (India)
Ltd., Coimbatore has a programme wherein 1015 cotton farmers form a SHG which has office
bearers who work with company under contract
and various other agencies like banks and monitor
the performance of the group as far as contract
is concerned. The National Dairy Development
Board (NDDB, a development agency's) Fruit and
Vegetable project, now under the Mother Dairy
Fruits and Vegetables Limited fSafal' brand),
procures fresh produce directly from 75 Growers1
Associations, with 15000 growers in north Indian

Figure.2: Tri-partite contract farming model
Payment for produce

Company

------------

*

Bank

Farmer/AoF/
Cooperative

Contract Farming for Agricultural Development

13

states and provides all inputs and information
(Chopra, n.d.).

5.2 Practice of Contract Farming
India

in

There have been some studies of the contract
farming system in India recently. But, besides
describing the contract system and operations
of the companies, most of them look at the
economics of the contract farming system in
specific crops, compared with that of the non­
contract situation and/or competing traditional
crops of a given region, e.g. in gherkins (hybrid
cucumber) in Tamil Nadu (Chidambaram, 1997),
Karnataka (Subrahmanyam, 2000) and Andhra
Pradesh (Haque, 1999; Dev and Rao, 2004) and
in tomato in Punjab (Bhalla and Singh, 1996;
Haque, 1999; Rangi and Sidhu, 2000), Karnataka
(Subrahmanyam, 2000), and Haryana (Dileep
et. al., 2002). It is found that contract produc­
tion gave much higher (almost three times)
gross returns compared with that from the tradi­
tional crops of wheat, paddy and potato in case
of tomato (Bhalla and Singh, 1996; Rangi and
Sidhu, 2000), and tomato and onion in the case
of gherkin (Chidambaram, 1997) due to higher
yield and assured price under contracts. The
studies of tomato contract production in Punjab
and Haryana (Haque, 1999; Dileep et. al., 2002)
and of gherkins in Andhra Pradesh (Haque,
1999; Dev and Rao, 2004) also found the net
returns from these crops under contracts being
much higher than those under non-contract situ­
ations though production cost was also higher
under contract system (Dileep et. al, 2002).
Contract growers in Punjab and Haryana faced
many problems like undue quality cut on pro­
duce by firms, delayed deliveries at the factory,
delayed payments, low price and pest attack on
the crop (Bhalla and Singh, 1996; Singh, 2000a;
Rangi and Sidhu, 2000; and Dileep et. al., 2002;
Satish, 2003). But, more recently, HLL's tomato
processing plant in Punjab (bought from Pepsi in
1995) has been shut down for the last one year.
Also, most of the firms work mostly with large
and medium farmers and contracts are biased
against the farmers (Bhalla and Singh, 1996;
Singh 2000a; Satish, 2003) with the exception
of firms in Andhra Pradesh and Karnataka which

14 Review of Theory and Practice with Special Reference to India

worked with small and marginal farmers due to
the nature of the crop (gherkin) itself (Haque,
1999; Dev and Rao, 2004). Breach of contracts
by farmers as well as firms has been reported
(Bhalla and Singh, 1996; Singh 2000a).
Some of these studies recommend further
expansion and promotion of contract farming
system due to its benefits (Bhalla and Singh,
1996; Chidambaram, 1997; Rangi and Sidhu,
2000; Subrahmanyam, 2000, and Dileep et. al.,
2002; Sidhu, 2002). The contract tree farming
schemes also did not do well for many reasons
which were mainly related to the design of con­
tract farming schemes and the management of
the projects by the companies and their partner
institutions (Saigal and Kashyap, 2002). Further,
there are issues of monopsony of the processing/marketing firm and its disinterest in more
backward areas where farmers need such inter­
ventions, besides the more crucial question of
sharing of value added surplus in processing and
marketing which are at the centre of whether
contract farming can contribute to more broad­
based agricultural development (Gill, 2004).

5.3 Changing Dynamics of Contract Farm­
ing in India: The Consortium Approach
Recently, several agribusiness companies have
made forays into the farm service sector, which
is being seen as private sector participation in
agricultural development. They are facilitators of
contract farming systems most of the time. One
such model is that of Mahindra Shubhlabh Ser­
vices Limited (MSSL) which has an agreement
with the Government of Punjab to facilitate con­
tract farming of maize in one lakh acres for diver­
sification for supply to AGS of Indonesia through
PAFC. It plans to capture 16 percent of the agri
input market by 2005 and increase farmer profit­
ability by 35-60 percent by better and cost effec­
tive input supply and better value realisation from
farm produce by finding better markets. For this,
it will leverage its tractor brand, strong customer
base, dealer network and first mover advantage.
Its product portfolio includes seeds, pesticides,
fertilisers, irrigation systems, equipment rent­
als, post harvest services, information provision,
and finance. For this purpose, various partners

i.e. retail chains, NGOs, agri input companies,
logistics companies, farm equipment companies,
food companies, and agri finance corporations
and banks, besides agricultural universities and
research centers are networked into the proj­
ect. The company offers extension services to
farmers for a fee but ensures a certain level of
yield. If farmers get lower than the assured
level of yield, then they need not pay the fee.
This experiment of the company in Madurai in
Tamil Nadu, where farmers had to pay Rs. 500
per acre, achieved assured yield in 75 percent of
the cases in the first year, which increased to 80
percent in the second year, despite drought con­
ditions. This ensures that the yield risks are low,
and therefore, insurance scheme can be imple­
mented (Naik, 2002; Sulaiman et. al. 2004). The
MSSL plays the role of an integrated farming
solutions provider. Other crops planned under
the company's operations in the state are mus­
tard, castor, pulses and vegetables.
This is similar to what has already been imple­
mented by Rallis India in M.P., Maharashtra, Kar­
nataka and Haryana. The company provides all
the inputs, technical support and finance to the
registered growers for a specific crop and facili­
tates the sale of produce at reasonable price. The
company follows a consortium approach (Figure

3). It has tied up with banks like ICICI and SBI
and with buyers of produce like HLL, Picric and
Cargill. The system is run through a network of
10 Rallis Kissan Kendras (RKKs) across the coun­
try. For example, a farmer can avail of a loan
upto Rs. 6500 per acre for basmati cultivation in
Panipat for a six-month period at a rate of inter­
est of 13 percent per annum. In addition, every
member farmer has accident insurance coverage
of Rs. 1 lakh.

The RKK has trained farmers to harvest basmati
when moisture levels are at 16 percent as har­
vesting at lower levels can lead to more broken
basmati grains during milling. The farmers are
paid prevailing market prices. The Rallis and the
ICICI bank deduct the cost of inputs and the
loan amount from the proceeds before paying
the farmer on the spot (Karunakaran, 2002).
The bank has been able to get 10 percent loan
guarantee from the buying company in case of
default by the company. Encouraged by this
project, the company has set up new projects
in fruits at Bangalore, and vegetables at Nasik.
The ICICI bank collaborated with the company
as they benefited from the rural penetration of
Rallis, and the HLL gained as it could get good
quality wheat for processing it into wheat flour
(Subrahmaniam, 2002).

Figure 3 : The Quad-partite contract farming model

-Contract Farming for Agricultural Development

15

The ICICI Bank lays down pre-set criteria for
farmer selection and informs input companies.
The input companies/bank officials do the docu­
mentation, input companies supply the inputs
and send detailed accounts to the bank, which
debits farmer account and credits input company
account. At the time of harvest, the processing/marketing company collects produce and
pays the bank its dues and rest to the farmer.
The bank credits the farmer's account and the
account is closed. An MoU among the bank,
the input company and the output company is
signed for the above arrangement. An undertak­
ing from the farmer to supply produce under this
scheme to the output company is taken by the
bank. The ICICI Bank prefers four sector proj­
ects as against tri-partite projects as it consid­
ers inputs service very crucial for cost reduction
and quality enhancement leading to better value
realisation for the farmer. The bank provided a
total of Rs. 180 crore as loans for various con­
tract farming projects during 2002-2003. The
bank-funded project has a 'credit plus' approach
which involves not only credit and input supply
but also extension service and marketing sup­
port. The bank also funded projects in basmati
rice, chillies, potato and cotton besides wheat.
It aims at raising prices of agriculture produce
and lowering cost to make farming viable for
the growers (Sabarinath, 2003). The Rallis' joint
venture project with the Government of Madhya
Pradesh, in which ICICI Bank is involved, started
three years ago with 250 acres of wheat with
50 farmers. Now, there are 15000 acres under
wheat cultivation.
The agribusiness facilitators are 'new players'
with knowledge and resources and strategy for
sustained growth through partnership for sus­
tainability. They will make money while helping

The bank-funded project has
a 'credit plus' approach which
involves not only credit and input
supply but also extension service
and marketing support.

Review of Theory and Practice with Special Reference to India

others, including farmers, make money. Their
strategies involve bundling of inputs and linking
up of credit with input supply which is the agri­
business of the 21st century (Boehlje et al, 1995).
But what is wrong with it if it can provide what
state and co-operatives have not been able to
provide for so long, i.e., timely and cost effective
supply of quality inputs and finance and even
tractors, and combine harvesters etc. on hire
basis and assured market for produce? Unfortu­
nately, what local panchayats and farmer groups
could not do (e.g. custom hiring out of tractors)
is being done by agribusiness companies. They
focus on more efficient use of modern inputs
with a two-pronged strategy, i.e., yield increase
or cost reduction through inputs and value addi­
tion (market improvement). This is a must for
competitiveness whether domestic or interna­
tional where quality and cost effectiveness are
the driving forces. More recently, the facilitator
model has been modified with the inclusion of a
local art/7/ya/commission agent/input dealer as a
franchisee for the agri facilitator (Figure. 4; also
Sulaiman et al, 2004). It is more of a case of an
inter locking of factor markets coming back in
another form. But, this model also does not seem
to be working well as there are many problems
in this model in Punjab though it has worked well
in some other states like Tamil Nadu.

5.4 State-led Contract Farming
The contract-farming programme launched by
the Punjab Government in October 2002 (for
the rabi season) was aimed at taking away 10
lakh hectares from the wheat-paddy rotation
over the next five years as part of the crop
adjustment programme, as recommended by
the second (2002) Johl Committee. In 2002,
a total of 29,000 acres had been proposed by
the PAFC under the programme, implemented
jointly by the Department of Agriculture, Punjab
Agro Industries Corporation (PAIC through its
subsidiary Punjab Agro Foodgrains Corporation
(PAFC)) and the private companies. The PAFC
not only provided seeds purchased from reputed
seed companies like Adventa India Limited and
Pro-Agro Limited and technical supervision, and
follow up on agronomic practices to the contract
growers, but also promised to buy back the

entire produce at pre-agreed prices through a tri­
partite agreement involving PAFC, seed company
through its dealer, and the farmer (Figure 5).

The tri-partite agreement specifies the fixed price
and bonus to be paid by the PAFC to farmer for
the produce (bonus only if the PAFC is able to sell
the produce at a higher price), type and quantity
of seed to be supplied by the seed company at a
given price for given acreage, farmer's responsi­
bility of delivering the quality produce (produced
by making use of recommended inputs bought
from outlets prescribed by the PAFC) at a speci­
fied place, payment within two days after deliv­
ery and PAFC being the sole decider of weight
of produce and the sole and only arbitrator in
case of dishonouring of the contract by any of
the parties. The contract is signed by the three
parties in the presence of two witnesses for
the farmer.
Towards the end of harvesting season for the
contracted crops, the programme had run into

rough weather. The contracted winter maize
and hyola crops failed almost completely due
to inclement weather and poor quality seeds
(Grewal, 2003). In case of green peas, the con­
tract growers were forced to dump their produce
in open market, after being rejected by the PAIC
on quality ground as per the contract specifica­
tion, as there had been fungus infection due to
inclement weather which was marked by heavy
rains in winter season and then sudden rise in
temperature. An area of 500 acres under contract
production of green peas in Patiala and Fatehgarh
Sahib districts had been affected. Some farmers
found fault with the fungicide supplied by the
contracted company in this regard. The dumping
of contract-produced crop in open market led to
fall in local market prices and it was being sold
at Rs. 3 per kg. now as against a promised price
of Rs. 5 per kg. by the PAIC (Singh, 2003; Rangi
and Sidhu, 2003). In general, across crops and
regions, the contract farming programme could
not achieve the stated area goal. Not only it fell
short in terms of contracted area being less than

Figure 4: The five-partite CF in India

Contract Farming for Agricultural Development

Figure.5: State-led contract farming system in Punjab (Tri-partite
agreement among farmer, seed company/dealer and PAFC)

Input co./
Dealer

that stated by the agency, but also the farm­
ers did not plant the entire contracted area with
the contract crops. The gap was much larger in
latter case and even as high as 50 percent in
winter maize in Ludhiana and 20 percent in hyola
in both Ludhiana and Patiala. There was a differ­
ent private seed company for each crop and they
only provided seed and no other extension ser­
vice. Finally, none of the companies procured the
produce and advised the farmers to sell in open
market, either because open market prices were
higher than contract price, or quality was not as
desired. Except the oilseed crops (hyola and sun­
flower), the net returns from contract crops were
found be lower than what farmers would have
got from wheat crop. Most of the problems farm­
ers faced related to production and quality (like
quality of seed and extension) and not marketing
of produce (except peas) as open market could
take care of contract produce. Due to this expe­
rience, a large majority (60 percent) were not
willing to enter into contract farming arrange­
ment again (Dhaliwal et al, 2003).
The Government of Punjab has now resigned
to a role of the facilitator of contract farming in
the state. The Governments of Uttar Pradesh
and Punjab have recently amended the APMC
Act which did not permit farmer level (direct)

Review of Theory and Practice with Special Reference to India

procurement by companies. This legal reform
process is being accelerated by the Indian gov­
ernment with the enactment of the amended
State Agricultural Produce Marketing (Devel­
opment and Regulation) Act, 2003 which now
permits setting up of private markets, selling of
produce by growers outside the APMCs (regu­
lated markets), setting up of direct markets,
specialised commodity specific markets, regu­
lation and promotion of contract farming, pro­
vision for agencies and measures to promote
quality, standards, and alternative markets, and
public-private partnerships to facilitate more
and better linkage between firms and farmers
(Gol, 2004). The amended APMC Act has both
mandatory and optional provisions in a model
contract farming agreement wherein mandatory
provisions specify who can undertake contract
farming activity, contract specifications, liabili­
ties, farmer asset indemnity, and dispute reso­
lution. The optional provisions are about farm
practices, insurance, monitoring of crops, role
of farmer bodies, and support to the contract
farmers. It also makes it mandatory to register
contract farming activity with a local authority
and is quite fair contract in terms of sharing
of costs and risks (Gol, 2003). Further, futures
trading has been permitted in 54 commodities
(Landes and Gulati, 2004).

6. Conclusions and Policy Suggestions
Given the nature of modern farming involv­
ing tremendous amount of technological input
and market orientation which require capital
resources, it is but inevitable to involve pri­
vate corporate business interests in agricultural
development through contract farming system.
The above discussion suggests that it is not the
contract per se which spells hardship or doom
for small growers as a system, but how it is
practised in a given context. In fact, all over the
world, contracting of some kind is a necessity for
many or most forms of modern commercial agri­
culture. Though there are some scholars who
caution about the widespread applicability of
contract farming as a development tool (Glover,
1987), if there are enough mechanisms to moni­
tor and use the contract for developmental pur­
poses, it has the potential to lead to a better­
ment of all the parties, especially the small and
marginal farmers (Table 1).

Contracts require frequent and independent
scrutiny so that they remain competitive both
with similar contracts and with open market
transactions. Wide publicity of contract terms
will help to stimulate competition. From the
producers' point of view, specific points to be
considered in negotiating the contract terms
include the method of determining the produc­
ers' price, adjustments for quality differentials,
allowance for climatic variations, farm practices,
credit terms, provisions for renewal and termi­
nation of contracts and for arbitration (Hill and
Ingersent, 1987). Though the state regulation of
contracts is desirable, but if the firms really want
to sabotage the contract, there is no way they
can be prevented from doing so (Glover, 1987;
Glover and Kusterer, 1990). Therefore, vigorous
bargaining co-operatives or other agricultural
producer organisations are needed to negotiate
equitable contracts. This kind of organisations
have been able to secure the standardisation
of contracts and their scrutiny by a government
agency in the US (Wilson, 1986).

The other tools of mitigating loss of control used

by farmers in the first world have been the peti­
tioning of the state for intervention to regulate
the contracts, the formation of producer bargain­
ing units, and the formation of farmers' markets
(Welsh, 1997). The difficulty in collective action
arises due to the heterogeneity of farmers and
the conflict between the self-interest and the
collective interest. Each farmer views his rela­
tionship with the company as an individualised
one (Glover, 1987; Kirk, 1987; Rickson and
Burch, 1996).

The social divisiveness of contract farming
would be lessened if more of the ' contractors'
were agricultural co-operatives or other pro­
ducer-oriented organisations. However, it has
to be recognised that agricultural co-operatives
may be deterred from attempting to integrate
forward into processing and distribution, both
by financial constraints and by the managerial
problem of making a success of unfamiliar activi­
ties in the face of strong competition (Hill and
Ingersent, 1987). There have also been experi­
ences of complete failure when co-operatives or
state agencies were contractors (White, 1997).
Working with farmer co-operatives for better and
more sustainable contract procurement by pri­
vate agribusiness firms seems to work for both
the parties. This is an experiment being tried
out by Marico Industries in Maharashtra state
of India in safflower oilseeds. The company pro­
vided working capital, infrastructural facilities,
managerial inputs, and contract job crushing
which helped the crushing unit co-operatives to
become viable (Bharadwaj and Palan, n.d.).
As a solution to the problems of the traditional
co-operatives which performed poorly and were
not member-focused, a new variant called New
Generation Co-operatives (NGCs) have come
up and evolved overtime in various parts of the
world like USA, Canada, and India (Harris et. al.
1996; Singh, 1997). A New Generation Co-oper­
ative is one which has restricted or limited mem­
bership, links product delivery rights to producer
member equity, raises capital through tradable

Contract Farming for Agricultural Development

19

Table 1: Relative benefits of alternative marketing structures for small farmers
Structure

Sales position of
small farmers (SF)
vis-a-vis large
farmers (LF)

Sales position of
SF vis-a-vis buyer

Input facilities/
Technical
assistance

Government
support required

Private local
firms (Nijjer in
Punjab)

Can be against SFs
due to bargaining
power

Advantage
of access to
alternative outlets

May be available/
based on local
experience

Provision of market
infrastructure, information,
ensuring competition, price
stabilisation

MNCs/large
firms (Pepsi,
HLL)

Equitable prices
through contract

Dependent but
secure if supplies
quality

Direct supply on
credit/ direct and
intensive

Should negotiate prices
and participation for SFs

Co-operatives
(Amul)

Equal if co­
operatives are
successful

Favourable if co­
operatives are
efficient

May arrange

Financial support

State boards/
bodies
(PAFC/HPMC)

Equal prices if
official buying
position could be
reached

May be exploited

Rare/left to other
govt, agencies

Insist on reaching small
farmers

Development
agency (NDDB)

- do --

Protected if
meets quality

Direct supply on
credit

Financial support required

Source: Adapted from J.C. Abbott (1993).

equity shares among membership, enforces con­
tractual delivery of produce by members, distrib­
utes returns based on patronage, goes for value
addition through processing or marketing, and
makes use of information efficiently through­
out the vertical system. However, it retains one
member-one vote principle for major policy deci­
sions. This kind of restructuring helps co-opera­
tives to tackle problems; of free riding by mem­
bership, of horizon which is at the root of finan­
cial constraint, and that of opportunism, both
of the members as well as of the co-operative.
This arrangement by co-operatives has helped
them become economically efficient, financially
viable, and obtain member loyalty wherever it
has been tried (Harris et.al., 1996). Additionally,
non-member procurement and quantity or acre­
age contracts have been also used by co-opera­
tives to tackle supply side problems (Hinman
and Ricks, 1993). Some of the co-operatives
like those dealing with sapota (chickoo) in south
Gujarat have also attempted quality based grad­
ing and pooling system, and contractual rela­
tions with members for procurement, along

0 Review of Theory and Practice with Special Reference to India

with market orientation strategies like multiple
outlets, and efficient use of market information
to achieve better business performance (Singh,
1997).

Though the amended APMC Act recognises con­
tract farming system now and has some provi­
sions to regulate it, a legal protection to contract
growers as a group is a must to protect them
from ill-effects of contracting (Wilson, 1986).
There are cases of legal protection given to sub­
contracting firms in Japan in their relations with
large firms. This set of laws specify the duties
(to have a written clear terms contract with the
sub-contractor) and forbidden acts for the large
parent firm. The forbidden acts include refusal to
receive delivery of commissioned goods, delaying
the payment beyond agreed period, discounting
of payment, returning commissioned goods with­
out good reason, forced price reduction, com­
pulsory purchase by sub-contractors of paren­
tal firm's products, and forcing sub-contractors
to pay in advance for materials supplied by the
parent firm. And, these provisions are monitored

by the Fair Trade Commission. Interestingly,
most of the violations by parent firms were on
the written form of contracts and clear terms of
the contracts (Sako, 1992). If contract farming
is nothing but the flexible production systems
prevalent in industry applied to farming, then it
is only logical to extend the legal provisions with
necessary modifications to farming contracts.
In some situations, it is not possible and easy to
build immediate partnerships. Therefore, there
can be a quasi-judicial system at the local level
(panchayat, district administration) to monitor
the contracts and resolve any conflict with appro­
priate penalties to any of the defaulting parties.
There has to be a general code of conduct for
both the parties in order to avoid conflicts and
breaking down of contracts. There should also
be incentives for better quality, timing, and care
of the crop (Glover and Kusterer, 1990). But,
contracting as a mechanism is desirable only if
the crop is perishable, non-bulky, perennial in
nature, needs heavy processing and strict quality
adherence (Goldsmith, 1985), credit market is in
a state of failure or there is a need to encour­
age new crops. But, still there are other options
which should be tried out i.e. state, NGOs for
credit and other inputs, and if contracting is a
must, then it should be regulated and monitored
(Grosh, 1994).
The important question is that of the division
of value added between the firm and the farm­
ers which is based on the relative bargaining
power of the parties involved (White, 1997).
Therefore, it is important to examine carefully
and design the pricing and other aspects of the
contracts. There is a role for the state agen­
cies and the NGOs to intervene in contract situ-

Though the amended APMC Act
recognises contract farming system
now and has some provisions to
regulate it, a legal protection to
contract growers as a group is a must
to protect them from ill-effects of
contracting.

ations as intermediaries to protect the farmer
and broader local community interests. The
NGOs can also play a role in information pro­
vision, and in monitoring and regulating the
working of contracts. Better co-operation and
co-ordination between companies and co-oper­
atives for agricultural development also needs
to be encouraged. Further, both companies and
state should promote group contracts with the
intermediation of local NGOs and other organi­
sations and institutions so that contractual rela­
tionships are more durable, enforceable, and
fair. An insurance component in farming inter­
ventions is a must to protect the farmer inter­
est and it is noted that some companies are
already doing it. But, the most important thing
is to ensure market for the farmer produce at
better price under these agribusiness projects.
What is also required is marketing extension in
terms of better product planning at the farmer
level, provision of market information, securing/accessing markets for farmers, provision
of alternative markets and market orientation
in terms of improved marketing practices at
the farmer level (Patnaik, 2003). Government
should also play an enabling role by legal provi­
sions and institutional mechanisms, like helping
farmer co-operatives and groups, to facilitate
smooth functioning of contract system.

Contract Farming for Agricultural Development

21

References
J C Abbott, 'Marketing, The Rural Poor and Sustain­
ability' in J C Abbott (ed.): Agricultural and Food
Marketing in Developing Countries - Selected
Readings, (Oxon: UK: CAB International 1993),
65-92
M Asano Tamanoi, ' Farmers, Industries, and the
State: The Culture of Contract Farming in Spain
and Japan', 30 (3) Comparative Studies in Soci­
ety and History, (1988), 432-452

P Baumann, 'Equity and Efficiency in Contract Farm­
ing Schemes: The Experience of Agricultural Tree
Crops', 139 ODI Working Paper, ODI, (London,
October, 2000).
G S Bhalla and G Singh, ' Impact of GATT on Punjab
Agriculture', (Delhi: Ajanta: 1996).
M Bharadwaj and J S Palan (n.d.): 'Co-operative Align­
ment with the Corporate - The New Direction',
mimeo. 4.

V Benziger, 'Small Fields, Big Money: Two Successful
Programmes in Helping Small Farmers Make the
Transition to High Value-Added Crops', 24 (11)
World Development, (1996), 1681-1693

Australasia Region, (USA: Avebury: Brookfield
1996), 107-126.

J A Carney, ' Struggles over Crop Rights and Labour
within Contract Farming Households in a Gam­
bian Irrigated Rice Project', 15 (3) The Journal of
Peasant Studies, (April, 1998), 334-349
Commonwealth Development Corporation, 1 & 2
Review of Smallholder Agricultural Programmes,
Final Report, (London: CDC: April 1989)
M Chidambaram, 'A Study of Export Potentials for
Gherkins (Hybrid Cucumber) in Tamil Nadu',
Department of Agricultural Economics, Centre
for Agriculture and Rural Development Studies,
Tamil Nadu Agricultural University (Coimbatore:
unpublished: 1997).

S R Christensen, 'Between the Farmer and the State:
Towards a Policy Analysis of the Role of Agri­
business in Thai Agriculture', Thailand Devel­
opment Research Institute (TDRI) Background
Report to the 1992 Conference on Thailand's
Economic Structure: Towards Balanced Devel­
opment?, Chon Buri, (Thailand: 1992).

M Boehlje, J Akridge and D Downey, ' Restructuring
Agribusiness for the 21st Century', 11 (6) Agri­
business, (1995), 493-500

RAJ Clapp, ' Representing Reciprocity, Reproducing
Domination: Ideology and the Labour Process
in Latin American Contract Farming', 16 (1) The
Journal of Peasant Studies, (1998) 5-39.

M Buch-Hansen and H S Marcussen, 'Contract Farming
and the Peasantry: Cases from Western Kenya',
23 Review of African Political Economy, (1982),
9-36

J L Collins, 'Gender, Contracts and Wage Work-Agri­
cultural Restructuring in Brazil's Sao Francisco
Valley', 24 (1) Development and Change, (Janu­
ary, 1993) 53-82.

D Bulow and A Sorensen, 'Gender and Contract Farm­
ing: Tea Outgrower Schemes in Kenya', 56 Review
ofAfrican Political Economy, (1993), 38-52

K Currie and L Ray, 'On the Class Location of Con­
tract Farmers in the Kenyan Economy', 15 (4)
Economy and Society, (1986) 445-475.

D Burch, 'Globalised Agriculture and Agri-food Restruc­
turing in South East Asia: The Thai Experience'
in D Burch, R E Rickson and G Lawrence (eds.):
Globalisation and Agri-Food Restructuring - Per­
spectives from the Australasia Region, (USA:
Avebury: Brookfield 1996), 323-344

V Deshpande, 'Cottoning on to Contracts', The Indian
Express, (4 April, 2003), 11

D Burch, and B Pritchard, ' The Uneasy Transition to
Globalisation: Restructuring of the Australian
Tomato Processing Industry' in D Burch, R E
Rickson and G Lawrence (eds.) Globalisation and
Agri-Food Restructuring - Perspectives from the

S M Dev and N C Rao, 'Food Processing in Andhra
Pradesh - Opportunities and Challenges', 57
Working Paper Series, Centre for Economic and
Social Studies (CESS), (CESS: Hyderabad: June,
2004).
H S Dhaliwal, M Kaur, and J Singh, Evaluation of
Contact Farming Scheme in the Punjab State',
Department of Economics, PAU, (Ludhiana:

2003)

Review of Theory and Practice with Special Reference to India

B K Dileep, R K Grover, and K N Rai, ' Contract Farm­
ing in Tomato: An Economic Analysis', 57 (2)
Indian Journal ofAgricultural Economics, (2003)
197-210.
D Dunham, 'Crop Diversification and Export Growth:
Dynamics of Change in the Sri Lankan Peas­
ant Sector', 24 (4) Development and Change,
(October, 1993) 787-813.

—, 'Contract Farming and Export Horticulture: Can
Agribusiness revitalise the Peasant Sector in Sri
Lanka?' 3 Agricultural Policy Series, Institute of
Policy Studies, IPS, (Colombo: February, 1995)

C Eaton, and AW Shepherd: Contract Farming: Partner­
ships for Growth - A Guide, FAO (Rome: 2001)
ALA Fulton, and R J Clark: ' Farmer Decision-making
under Contract Farming in Northern Tasmania'
in D Burch, R E Rickson and G Lawrence (eds.):
ibid, (1996), 219-237.
S S Gill, 'Small Farmers and Markets' (a book review),
39 (23) Economic and Political Weekly, (June 5,
2004), 2356-2358.

Gol (Govt, of India): Economic Survey 2003-04, Min­
istry of Finance, Gol, (New Delhi: 2004)

D J Glover, 'Increasing the Benefits to Smallholders
from Contract Farming: Problems for Farmers'
Organisations and Policy Makers, World Devel­
opment, 15(4), (April, 1987), 441-448.
D Glover and K Kusterer: Small Farmers, Big Business
- Contract Farming and Rural Development,
(Macmillan: London: 1990).
D Glover, and L T Ghee (eds.): Contract Farming in
South East Asia - Three Country Studies, Kuala
Lumpur, University of Malaya. (1992)
A Goldsmith, 'The Private Sector and Rural Develop­
ment: Can Agribusiness Help the Small Farmer?',
World Development, 13 (10-11), (1985),
1125-1138.

D Goodman, B Sorj, and J Wilkinson: From Farming
to Biotechnology: A Theory of Agro-industrial
Development, (Oxford: Basil Blackwell: 1987)

MGrewal, 'Cropped by Corporates', The Indian Express,
Ahmedabad, April 27, The Sunday Express Sec­
tion, III. (2003)

B Grosh, ’ Contract Farming in Africa: An Application of
the New Institutional Economics', 3(2) Journal of
African Economies, 231-261, (1994).
T Haque, (1999): Contract Farming in India, National
Centre for Agricultural Economics and Policy
Research (New Delhi: unpublished).

A Harris, B Stefanson, and M Fulton: 'New Generation
Co-operatives and Co-operative Theory', Journal
of Co-operatives, Volume II, (1996), 15-28.
Y Hayami and A Damodaran: 'Towards an Alterna­
tive Agrarian Reform - Tea Plantations in South
India', 39 (36) Economic and Political Weekly,
(September 4-10, 2004), 3992-3997.

B E Hill and K A Ingersent: An Economic Analysis of
Agriculture, (London: Heinemann: 1987)

L D Hinman and D J. Ricks: ’ Co-operatives, Mar­
keting Orders and the Coordination of Supply
and Demand for Perennial Crops in the U.S.', in
Csaba Csaki and Yoan Kislev (eds.) Agricultural
Co-operatives in Transition, (Westview Press:
Boulder: U.S.A.: 1993)
ITCOT: Report on Contract Farming, Industrial and
Technical Consultancy Organisation of Tamil
Nadu, (ITCOT) (Chennai: 2004)
N Karunakaran: Money Grows on Trees...', Intelli­
gent Investor, (from: ISAP@yahoogroups.com).
(August 31, 2002)
N Key and D Runsten: ’ Contract Farming, Small­
holders, and Rural Development in Latin Amer­
ica: The Organisation of Agroprocessing Firms
and the Scale of Outgrower Production', World
Development, 27 (2) (1999) 381-401.
C Kirk, ' Contracting Out: Plantations, Smallholders
and Transnational Enterprise', IDS Bulletin, 18
(2), (April, 1987), 45-51.

P Konings, ’Unilever, Contract Farmers and Co-opera­
tives in Cameroon: Crisis and Response', 26
(1) The Journal of Peasant Studies, (October,
1998), 112-138.
T Korovkin, 'Peasants, Grapes, and Corporations - The
Growth of Contract farming in a Chilean Com­
munity', 19 (2) The Journal of Peasant Studies,
(January, 1992) 228-254.

Contract Farming for Agricultural Development ”23

R Landes and A Gulati-. 'Farm Sector Performance and
Reform Agenda', 39(32) Economic and Political
Weekly, (August 7-13, 2004), 3611-3619.
K M Leisinger, 'Multinational Companies and Agricul­
tural Development - A case study of Taona Zina’
in Madagascar’, Food Policy, (August, 1987),
227-241.
R G Lewis: 'Contract Growing of Flue-cured Tobacco
in Jamaica', in John Freivalds (ed.): Success­
ful Agribusiness Management, (Vermont: USA:
Gower: 1985) 182-188.

P D Little: 'Contract Farming and the Development
Question' in Little, Peter D and Michael J Watts
(eds.): Living Under Contract - Contract Farm­
ing and Agrarian Transformation in Sub-Saharan
Africa, Madison, (University of Wisconsin Press:
1994) 216-247.
P D Little and M J Watts (eds.) (1994): ibid.
S Mitra and A Sarkar 'Relative Profitability from Pro­
duction and Trade - A Study of Selected Potato
Markets in West Bengal', 38(44) Economic
and Political Weekly, (November 1, 2003)
4694-4699.
B Morvaridi: 'Contract Farming and Environmental Risk
- The Case of Cyprus', 23 (1) The Journal of Peas­
ant Studies, (October 1995), 30-45.

M Nanda: 'Transnationalisation of Third World State
and Undoing of Green Revolution', 30(4) Eco­
nomic and Political Weekly, PE20-PE30, (January
28, 1995).
G Naik: 'Enhancing Food Security through Market
Reforms'43 (1), Productivity,, (2002), 60-66.
G Patnaik: 'Marketing, Storage, and Extension Ser­
vices: State of Agriculture in India' in Bibek
Debroy and A U Khan (eds.): Enabling Agricul­
tural Markets for the Small Indian Farmer, Book­
well (New Delhi: 2003), 81-120.
G Porter and K Phillips-Howard: 'Farmers, Labourers
and the Company: Exploring Relationships on
a Transkei Contract Farming Schemes', 32 (1)
The Journal of Development Studies, (October,
1995), 55-73.

—, 'Comparing Contracts: An Evaluation of Con­
tract Farming Schemes in Africa) 25 (2) World
Development, (1997) 227-238.

------ —----- 24) Review of Theory and Practice with Special Reference to India

C Payer: 'The World Bank and the Small Farmer', 32
(6) Monthly Review, (1980) 30-46.

P S Rangi and M S Sidhu: 'A Study on Contract Farm­
ing of Tomato in Punjab', 42(4) Agricultural Mar­
keting, (2000) 15-23.
—, 'Contract Farming in Punjab', 44(3) Productivity,
(2003), 484-491.

R E Rickson and D Burch: 'Contract Farming in
Organisational Agriculture: The Effects upon
Farmers and the Environment' in D Burch, R E
Rickson and G Lawrence (eds.): op.cit., (1996),
173-201.
M Sabarinath: Corp India gets Agro as States sign up
Exec Farmers, The Economic Times, (Ahmedabad: April 14, 2003) 1.

L M Sachikoyne: 'The State and Agribusiness in Zim­
babwe: Plantations and Contract Farming',
Leeds Southern African Studies No. 13, African
Studies Unit, Department of Politics, University
of Leads, (August 1989).
S Saigal and D Kashyap: Review of Company-Farmer
Partnerships for the Supply of Raw Material to
Wood-based Industry, India Country Sub-study
published by Eco-tech Services (India) Pvt. Ltd.,
New Delhi and International Institute for Envi­
ronment and Development (IIED), (London:
2002).
M Sako: Prices, Quality and Trust - Inter-firm relations
in Britain and Japan, (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press: 1992).

P Satish: 'Contract Farming as a Backward Linkage
for Agro Processing - Experiences from Punjab',
unpublished paper, abstract published in the
Indian Journal ofAgricultural Economics, 58(3),
p. 603. (2003).
C D Scott: 'Transnational Corporations and Asymme­
tries in the Latin American Food System', Bul­
letin of Latin American Research, 3(1), 63-80,
(January, 1984)

V Shiva and T Crompton: 'Monopoly and Monocul­
ture- Trends in Indian Seed Industry', Eco­
nomic and Political Weekly, 33(39), (1998),
A137-A151
K Siddiqui: 'Agricultural Exports, Poverty and Eco­
logical Crisis - Case Study of Central Ameri-

can Countries', 33(39) Economic and Political
Weekly, (1998), A128-A136
H S Sidhu: 'Crisis in Agrarian Economy in Punjab
- Some Urgent Steps', 37 (30) Economic and
Political Weekly, July 27, Review of Agriculture,
(2002), 3132-3138.

J Singh: 'Contracted Green Peas Dumped in Open
Market', The Tribune, (Chandigarh: March 28,
2003), 15.
S Singh: 'Managing Marketing: Co-operatives in
Horticultural Business in South Gujarat', 11
(1&2) Indian Journal of Agricultural Marketing,
(1997).
—, 'Crisis in Punjab Agriculture', 35(23) Eco­
nomic and Political Weekly, (June 3-9, 2000),
1889-1892.

—, 'Contract Farming for Agricultural Diversification
in the Indian Punjab: A Study of Performance
and Problems' 56 (3) Indian Journal of Agricul­
tural Economics, (2000), 283-294.
—, 'Contracting Out Solutions: Political Economy
of Contract Farming in the Indian Punjab', 30(9)
World Development, (September, 2002) 16211638.

—, 'Contract Farming in India: Impacts on Women
and Child Workers', the Gatekeeper Series Paper
No. Ill, International Institute for Environment
and Development (IIED), (London: 2003).

K V Subrahmanyam: 'Linkages Between Farm and
Non-Farm Sector: Role of Processing of Horti­
cultural Products', NABARD Occasional Paper
No. 16, National Bank for Agriculture and Rural
Development (NABARD), (Mumbai: 2000).
Subramaniam, A (2002): 'Field Day in Store for Farm­
ers', in http://www.tata.com/rallis_ india/articles
/2002060_ farming, htm.

R V Sulaiman, A J Hall and N Suresh: 'Effectiveness
of Private Sector Extension in India and Les­
sons for the New Extension Policy Agenda' an
unpublished paper presented at the workshop
on 'Rural Innovations - Emphasising the post­
harvest sector', organised by CRISP, Hyderabad
at ICRISAT, Hyderabad during November (2004)
22-29.
G Torres: The Force of Irony: Power in the Everyday
Life of Mexican Tomato Workers (Oxford: Berg:
1997)

USAID (United States Agency for International Devel­
opment): Assessment of Contract Farming in
Lam Nam Oon, Thailand, Centre for Develop­
ment Information and Evaluation, USAID work­
ing paper No. 193, USAID and the The Royal
Thai Government, (April 1994)
M Watts: 'Peasants and Flexible Accumulation in the
Third World - Producing under Contract', 27 (30)
Economic and Political Weekly, (1992), PE90PE97.
R Welsh: 'Vertical Co-ordination, Producer Response,
and the Locus of Control over Agricultural Pro­
duction Decisions', 62(4) Rural Sociology, (1997)
491-507, winter.

B White: 'Agro-industry and Contract Farming in
Upland Java', 24(3) The Journal of Peasant
Studies, (April, 1997), 100-136.
S Williams and R Karen: Agribusiness and the Small
Scale Farmer: A Dynamic Partnership for Devel­
opment, (London: Westview Press: 1985).

J Wilson: 'The Political Economy of Contract Farming',
18(4) Review of Radical Political Economics,
(1986), 47-70.

A Winson: 'Capitalist Coordination of Agriculture:
Food Processing Firms and Farming in Central
Canada', 55(3) Rural Sociology, (1990), 376394, Fall.

Contract Farming for Agricultural Development

25

Centre for Trade and Development (Centad) was established by
Oxfam GB in 2004, as a not-for-profit organisation, to carry out policy
research and advocacy on issues around trade and development,
with a principal focus on South Asia.

Clelnltlald
Centre for Trade 4 Development

An Oxfam GB Initiative

# 406, Bhikaiji Cama Bhavan
Bhikaiji Cama Place
New Delhi - 110066
Tel: + 91 - 11 -51459226
Fax: + 91 - 11 -51459227
Email: centad@centad.org
Web: www.centad.org

Position: 2607 (2 views)